The role of imports for exporter performance in Peru

AuthorThomas Farole,Ana Margarida Fernandes,Martha Denisse Pierola
Date01 February 2018
Published date01 February 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12524
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The role of imports for exporter performance in Peru
Martha Denisse Pierola
1
|
Ana Margarida Fernandes
2
|
Thomas Farole
3
1
Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC, USA
2
Development Research Group, The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA
3
The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA
Funding information
Financial support from Macro and Fiscal Management Global Practice, Latin America Region, is gratefully acknowledged.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Supported by the commodities boom and a raft of policy liberalisations, Peru experienced a decade
of unprecedented growth that contributed to substantial poverty reduction. Between 2000 and
2013, Perus GDP per capita grew at 4.3% annually, a rate almost three times faster than the global
average and six times faster than its average growth in the previous four decades. But as the com-
modity super-cycle unwinds, Peru faces a significant challenge of sustaining growth. Trade is one
potential growth engine that remains significantly under-exploited.
Even during the commodities boom, Peru exported far less than would be predicted by its income
level, and its import share of GDP (at 24.2%) was the 12th lowest in the world in 2013. Of course,
from a static growth accounting perspective, imports are a drain on growth. But with increasing con-
centration of non-commodity trade in global production networks or global value chains (GVCs)
where stages of production are separated and dispersed across locationsthe role of imported inputs
becomes crucial, both as a source of productivity-enhancing technology and as ticketto participa-
tion in GVCs. Peru remains a substantive laggard, with its participation in GVCs being highly con-
centrated in forward links to its commodity exports, with limited potential for productivity-enh ancing
spillovers. Importantly, Perus backward links in GVCsthe degree to which it makes use of
imported inputs in its export productsare among the lowest in the world. The share of foreign value
added embedded in Perus total exports stood at 14% in 2011, which is a much smaller percentage
than that of other developing countries deeply integrated in GVCs, such as Mexico and Malaysia.
1
1
The share of foreign value added embedded in a countrys total exports indicates what part of the countrys gross exports
consists of inputs produced in foreign countries (and thus is the share of the countrys exports not adding to its gross
domestic product). It is shown in Figure A1 for Peru and several comparator countries, based on data from UNCTADs
Eora database. The database uses information from a multiregion inputoutput table at the world level to estimate the import
content ratio in exportable products and value added in trade for a large number of countries (UNCTAD, 2013). The data-
base is part of the research agenda focusing on the importance of trade in intermediates and on measuring trade in value
added whose important contributions are in Koopman, Whang, and Wei (2014) or Johnson and Noguera (2012). Note that
this measure of the share of foreign value added differs from the measure of direct imports of intermediates we will use for
the analysis in this paper (which is closer to the concept of importing to exportproposed by Baldwin and Lopez-Gonzalez
(2015) measuring foreign intermediates used to produce goods and services that are subsequently exported).
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12524
550
|
©2017 The World Bank The World Economy
©2017 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec World Econ. 2018;41:550572.
Recognition of the importance of imported inputs for economic growth dates back to the
endogenous growth theory, where improvements in technology foster long-term growth and
imported inputs are a channel for the diffusion of global technology (Aghion & Howitt, 1998;
Grossman & Helpman, 1991; Romer, 1987; Romer, 1990).
2
Gains to productivity also arise from
the increased input variety ensuing from the use of imported intermediate inputs, in the presence
of imperfect substitution in production across domestic and imported intermediate inputs (Ethier,
1982). Extending initial empirical evidence at the aggregate level that imports of intermediate
inputs are positively correlated with aggregate productivity by Coe, Helpman, and Hoffmaister
(1997), a growing set of micro-level studies show that manufacturing firms benefit from their
access to imported intermediate inputs in terms of significantly higher productivity (e.g., Amiti &
Konings, 2007; Castellani, Serti, & Tomasi, 2010; Halpern, Koren, & Szeidl, 2015; Kasahara &
Rodrigue, 2008) and higher overall product scope (Goldberg, Khandelwal, Pavcnik, & Topalova,
2010).
Since imported inputs enhance firm productivity, they can also play a critical role for firm
export performance. Specifically, selection into exporting determined by firm productivity as in
Melitz (2003) can be strengthened by the firms access to imported inputs as shown in the hetero-
geneous firms trade model proposed by Kasahara and Lapham (2013). In this model, importing a
larger variety of intermediate inputs increases firm productivity via an increasing returns technol-
ogy. More productive firms can afford to incur in the sunk costs required to export and still be
profitable and thus are more likely to export.
3
Imported intermediate inputs are oftenespecially
for firms in developing countriesof higher quality than domestic inputs. Kugler and Verhoogen
(2012) propose a heterogeneous firms trade model where the use of higher-quality intermediate
inputs in production increases the quality of a firms output, leading to higher demand in export
markets (particularly those of high-income countries) and enhancing the firms likelihood of
exporting and its total exports.
4
Access to lower-priced imported inputs would also reduce costs
and increase profits from exporting, allowing firms previously unable to export to now afford the
required fixed costs.
In this paper, we test the aforementioned predictions from the literature on the role of imported
inputs for the export performance of firms in Peru. The countrys last decade is a particularly inter-
esting context in which to test these predictions given weak productivity growth, declining perfor-
mance of the export engine and the apparent failure to exploit the import channel which
represented a barrier to firm-level productivity, export competitiveness and ultimately economic
growth. We use highly disaggregated exporter-level and importer-level customs data for Peru over
a long period, from 2000 to 2012, to evaluate the relationship between imported intermediate
inputs and export performance for the overall export sector as well as for two leading non-minerals
export sectorsagribusiness, where Peru has achieved a strong position in global retail supply
chains and apparel, one of Perus largest manufacturing export sectors and among the most impor-
tant sectors traded in GVCs. We estimate premia for exporting firms that are also direct importers
relative to those that are not direct importers in a wide range of firm export performance
2
See Keller (2005) for a review of the literature on trade as a channel for the international transmission of technology.
3
Bas and Strauss-Kahn (2014) extend a simpler version of the model by Kasahara and Lapham (2013) where they assume
that the use of imported intermediate inputs explicitly reduces the fixed costs of exporting (in addition to increasing produc-
tivity).
4
Javorcik and Iacovone (2012) show that firms upgrade the quality of their products (as proxied by unit values) in prepara-
tion for entry into export markets. Hallak (2006) shows that consumers in higher-income countries are more willing to pay
for product quality, and Verhoogen (2008) proposes a model where firms choose to sell higher-quality varieties to richer
destination markets.
PIEROLA ET AL.
|
551

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT