The Role of Ideas in Antitrust Policy toward Vertical Mergers: Evidence from the FTC Cement-Ready Mixed Concrete Cases

AuthorRonald N. Johnson,Allen M. Parkman
Published date01 December 1987
Date01 December 1987
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0003603X8703200401
Subject MatterDomestic Antitrust
The Antitrust Bulletin/Winter 1987
The role
of
ideas in antitrust policy
toward vertical mergers:
evidence from the FTC
cement-ready mixed concrete cases
BY RONALD N. JOHNSON* and ALLEN M. PARKMAN**
841
Throughout the
1950s
and '60s, the antitrust authorities typically
took a hostile presumptive approach to vertical mergers.' More
recently, however, they have initiated areappraisal of the effects
of
vertical mergers on competition. Clear evidence
of
this reap-
praisal is contained in the Department
of
Justice's 1982 and 1984
Merger Guidelines.' These guidelines de-emphasize concerns
about vertical mergers by covering them in a section devoted to
Professor
of
Economics, Montana State University, Bozeman,
Montana.
•• Professor of Management, University of New Mexico, Albuquer-
que, New Mexico.
IThat attitude was reflected in a general hostility toward all merg-
ers. Dissenting from a 1966 opinion invalidating a horizontal merger,
Justice Stewart wrote,
"The
sole consistency that I can find is that in lit-
igation under [section] 7, the Government always wins." United States
v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270,
301
(Stewart,
J.,
dissenting).
21982Merger Guidelines, 47 Fed. Reg. 28,493 (1982);1984 Merger
Guidelines, 49 Fed. Reg. 26,824 (1984).The 1968 Merger Guidelines had
©1988by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
842 The antitrust bulletin
horizontal effects
of
nonhorizontal mergers. The Reagan Admin-
istration's proposed Merger Modernization Act of 1986 would go
even further by amending section 7
of
the Clayton Act.' The
stated purpose
of
the act is to make a clearer distinction between
mergers that would enhance efficiency in contrast to those that
would have the probability of significantly increasing prices to
consumers. The proposed act contains three amendments to the
Clayton Act: (1) to require that there be a "significant probabil-
ity" that a merger will be harmful before it is prohibited, (2) to
focus attention on
"market
power" as the anticompetitive harm
about which the Clayton Act is concerned, and (3) to set forth
specific factors that the court should consider as relevant. 4
While this reappraisal has been well received in some quarters,
it certainly has not been unanimously endorsed. The effects
of
vertical mergers on competition continue to be a controversial
topic in both law and economics. SSince all productive activities
are integrated to some extent, many commentators have argued
that vertical mergers will only occur when it is anticipated that
they will increase the efficiency
of
the combined firm." Others
have argued that the mergers are motivated by a desire
of
the
separate criteria for horizontal and vertical mergers. For vertical
mergers, a 10 percent share of the market for the upstream firm and 6
percent share for the downstream firm were established as the danger
points. 1968 Merger Guidelines, 2
TRADE
REG.
REP.
(CCH) , 4510
(1968).
3Department of Justice Press Release (Feb. 19, 1986).
4[d.
5For a recent discussion of these concerns, see E. Fox &J.
HALVERSON,
ANTITRUST
POLICY
IN
TRANSITION:
THE
CONVERGENCE
OF
LAW
AND
ECONOMICS
(1984).
6 In R.
BORK,
THE
ANTITRUST
PARADOX
245 (1978), the author con-
cludes,
"The
analysis set out in this chapter suggests that, in the
Vertical mergers :843
merging firms
to
increase their
market
power
by
creating
barriers
to
entry
through
foreclosure.'
Much
of
the
debate
has
been
of
a
theoretical
nature.
How-
ever,
the
agencies responsible for
the
implementation
of
the
antitrust
laws
have
faced apractical
problem
with
their
enforce-
ment
of
the
Clayton
Act's
restrictions
on
vertical mergers.
After
a
merger
has
been
culminated,
the
merged
company
often
becomes
so
intertwined
that
an
appropriate
remedy
may
be
difficult
to
construct.
8
The
difficulty
of
applying
an
appropriate
remedy
has
caused
the
enforcement
agencies to
evaluate
mergers in
their
"incipiency,"
rather
than
waiting to see
which
of
the
opposing
arguments
is valid." As a result, evaluations
have
been
made
with
limited empirical evidence
of
the
effects
of
the
proposed
mergers.
Since
the
effect
of
amerger
isto
be
judged
in its incipiency,
theories
about
the
probable
outcome
carry
substantial
weight.
Moreover,
as
Robert
Bork
notes,
".
. .
ideology
remains,
and
its
inner
logic drives
the
antitrust
enterprise-lawyers,
economists,
judges,
and
legislators-inexorably
toward
the
conclusions
im-
absence of a most unlikely proved predatory power and purpose, anti-
trust should never object to the verticality of any merger; much less
should it adopt the stance of virtual per se illegality reflected in Brown
Shoe and other cases."
7While this argument has generally not been popular among econ-
omists, the antitrust authorities and the courts have relied on the market
foreclosure doctrine as applied to vertical mergers in dealing with verti-
cal mergers. For a detailed discussion, see R.
BLAIR
&D.
KASERMAN,
LAW
AND
ECONOMICS
OF
VERTICAL
INTEGRATION
AND
CONTROL
147 (1983).
8The problems associated with fashioning adequate remedies are
documented in Elzinga, The Antimerger Law: Pyrrhic Victoriesr, 12
J.L.E. 43 (1969). The Elzinga study has recently been updated in Ro-
gowsky, The Economic Effectiveness
of
Section 7Relief, 31
ANTITRUST
BULLETIN
187 (1986).
9The need for early action was based on Congress' hope of catch-
ing the process of monopolization
"in
its incipiency," while not making
mergers per se illegal. A.
NEALE,
THE
ANTITRUST
LAWS
OF
THE
U.S.A. 180
(1970).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT