The Robinson–Patman Act and the Supreme Court, 1978-85

AuthorHarry L. Shniderman
Published date01 September 1986
Date01 September 1986
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0003603X8603100303
Subject MatterArticle
The
Antitrust
Bulletin/Fall 1986
The Robinson-Patman Act
and the Supreme Court, 1978-85
BY HARRY L. SHNIDERMAN*
I. Introduction
665
Some have said that the Robinson-Patman Act has lost most of
its steam as it has chugged along with diminishing attention from
the Federal Trade Commission and continued disregard by the
Department of Justice. Its 50 years of travel have certainly taken
a toll, but the act has hardly been taken
out
of service.
The 8-year period 1978-85 has produced an average
of
30
reported opinions per year and 7 Supreme Court decisions.
Indeed, a check of an earlier to-year period, 1956-65, discloses
on average 22 court opinions per year. So the perception
of
a
change in climate is largely due to governmental laxity of enforce-
ment.
Treble damage suits can be a heavy and expensive reminder
that private enforcement
of
the act is ever present. Such suits may
be unprincipled responses to dealer termination, territorial inva-
sion, suits for sums due under contracts, and real or fancied
grievances. The absence
of
any element
of
governmental policy
review before institution
of
action can produce some quixotic
litigation which may not be meritorious or even target those who
have taken undue business risks.
Senior Partner, Covington &Burling, Washington, D.C.
:s
1986 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
666 The antitrust bulletin
Most
of
these private suits reflect money judgment
risks-
often vast amounts of money. An FTC cease and desist order,
however, could require change in basic pricing and distribution
practices on a company-wide basis, as well as invite private
tag-along suits. On the assumption that the respondent's ques-
tioned pricing reflected management's judgment as to what was
best for the company's own welfare, the threat
of
investigation
and enforcement by the administrative agency exercised to at
least a limited degree a restraining influence. The more recent
absence of such restraint may have adversely affected industry
compliance with the statute. This result will not show up in any
bare recital
of
case statistics.
Seven Supreme Court decisions since 1978 show a continued
lively interest in the statute. These important Supreme Court
developments merit analysis to see how the law has been unfold-
ing in recent years.
It
is also useful to detect whether these
decisions promote pricing flexibility in keeping with Sherman Act
goals, or whether they foster a code of pricing conduct of some
uniformity and rigidity to protect business from aggressive com-
petition
of
anature viewed in populist terms as "unfair."
II. United States Gypsum Co.
The Sherman Act section 1 price-fixing conspiracy case
against major gypsum board manufacturers was decided by the
Supreme Court in June 1978. The jury had returned a guilty
verdict, and the Third Circuit had reversed. The case had become
strongly enmeshed with the Robinson-Patman Act. The competi-
tors had been exchanging price information and this exchange
was a central part
of
the government's case. The defendants
asserted by way
of
defense that the informational exchange
among sellers was merely an effort to verify competitive prices so
they could validly be met under section 2(b)
of
the Robinson-
Patman
Act.
The district court, in its somewhat ambiguous instruction,
permitted the
jury
to consider this claimed purpose
of
complying
The Supreme Court :667
with
Robinson-Patman.
On the other hand, the trial judge stated
that if the effect
of
price verification was to fix or stabilize prices,
the exchanges could be considered as evidence
of
the mutual
agreement. In short, the claimed
Robinson-Patman
Act defense
was
not
going to justify aSherman Act price-fixing arrangement.
The
Third Circuit, in reversing, held
that
the instruction was
erroneous;
that
there could be a "controlling circumstance"
under United States v. Container Corp. which would justify the
exchange
of
price information and prevent an antitrust law
violation occurring.
The
defendants were entitled
to
an instruction that their verification practice would not violate the
Sherman Act if the jury found: (1) the appellants
engaged
in the
practice solelyto complywith the strictures of Robinson-Patman; (2)
they had first resorted to all other reasonable means of corrobora-
tion, without
success;
(3) they had good, independent reason to
doubt the buyers' truthfulness; and
(4)
their communication with
competitors was strictly limited to the one price and one buyer at
issue.I
In short, the Third Circuit would permit a
Robinson-Patman
defense to the verification practice when used as a seller's last
resort in confirming
that
there was a
bona
fide lower offer from a
competitor
that
it could meet under section 2(b).
The
Supreme
Court,
in an opinion by Chief Justice Burger,
affirmed
the
reversal
of
the jury verdict on other grounds.' In
doing so, however, it categorically rejected the use
of
section 2(b)
to justify anticompetitive conduct which would otherwise consti-
tute
proof
of
Sherman Act price-fixing.
The majority found it unnecessary to consider whether there
is in fact a general "controlling circumstance" exception to a
United States v. United States Gypsum Co., 550
F.2d
115,
126
(3rd Cir.
1977),
citing United States v. Container Corp.,
398
U.S. 333,
335
(1969).
It
is doubtful that this charge would have aided defendants
on the facts.
It
was not a charge requested by the defendants.
2United States v. United States
Gypsum
Co., 438U.S. 422
(1978).
There were three separate opinions by JusticesPowell, Rehnquist, and
Stevens
concurring and dissenting in part on various
issues.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT