The Revival of Fairness Discourse in Competition Policy

AuthorMichael Trebilcock,Francesco Ducci
Published date01 March 2019
DOI10.1177/0003603X18822580
Date01 March 2019
Subject MatterArticles
Article
The Revival of Fairness Discourse
in Competition Policy
Francesco Ducci* and Michael Trebilcock**
Abstract
The resurrection of the free trade–fair trade debate at the international level parallels a renewed
pressure to incorporate fairness considerations within domestic competition policies, originating from
a perceived reduction in the level of competition in various industries. Both supporters and critics of
notions of fairness, however, have failed to advance a normatively persuasive case in their favor,
neglecting the multifaceted nature of fairness in the competition policy domain. In this article, we
disaggregate and evaluate four specific notions of fairness that are pertinent to domestic markets:
vertical fairness between producers and consumers, horizontal fairness on the demand side, horizontal
fairness on the supply side, and procedural fairness. We defend a narrow dimension of horizontal
fairness on the supply side consistent with efficiency goals and of procedural fairness in the enforce-
ment of competition laws. We conclude by comparing the free trade–fair trade debate with the return
of fairness in competition policy.
Keywords
antitrust, fairness, concentration, consumer welfare, due process
I. Introduction: The Revival of Fairness Discourse in Competition Policy
Fairness concerns are making their way back into the competition policy domain. As part of a broader
trend that, at the international level, sees the rise of economic nation alism and a political divide
between those favoring open versus closed bridges and of fair trade versus free trade debates,
1
in the
domestic context there are renewed demands to reset the balance between equity and efficiency of
markets through alternative competition policies more attuned to fairness considerations.
2
An
*SJD Candidate, University of Toronto, Faculty of Law, Toronto, ON, Canada
**Professor of Law & University Professor, University of Toronto, Toronto, ON, Canada
Corresponding Author:
Francesco Ducci, SJD Candidate, University of Toronto Faculty of Law, 84 Queen’s Park, Toronto, ON M5S 2C5, Canada.
Email: francesco.ducci@mail.utoronto.ca
1. See The Economist Special Report, In Defence of Globalization,THE ECONOMIST, Oct. 1, 2016.
2. See Competition Policy International, Antitrust’s Inequality Conundrum,1A
NTITRUST CHRON. (Fall 2017); Eleanor M. Fox,
Competition Policy at the Intersection of Equity and Efficiency,63A
NTITRUST BULL. 3–6 (2018); William J. Curran III,
Commitment and Betrayal: Contradictions in American Democracy, Capitalism and Antitrust Laws,61A
NTITRUST BULL.
236–55 (2016); Mauritius Dolmans & Wanjie Lin, Fairness and Competition Law: A Fairness Paradox,C
ONCURRENCES 4
The Antitrust Bulletin
2019, Vol. 64(1) 79-104
ªThe Author(s) 2019
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0003603X18822580
journals.sagepub.com/home/abx
increasing number of scholars and commentators have advocated stronger incorporation of equity
considerations into competition policy in order to address problems of wealth inequality, distributive
concerns, and more generally inequities of market outcomes through the enforcement of competition
laws.
3
Among others, Anthony Atkinson has argued that competition policy should embody explicit
distributional concern,
4
Joseph Stiglitz has called for stronger and more effective enforcement of
competition laws to help address inequalities created by market power,
5
and Paul Krugman has blamed
the collapse of antitrust enforcement as a potentially important factor in the stagnating demand for
labor and increasing inequality more generally.
6
Similarly, the current European Commissioner for
Competition, Margrethe Vestager, has repeatedly stressed the importance of fairness considerations in
competition rules.
7
In contrast, other commentators, including Hovenkamp and Crane, remain skep-
tical of the role of antitrust in tackling inequality.
8
Conard in particular has advanced skeptical views
about redistribution, arguing that consumers already capture almost all of the value of competition and
innovation.
9
He finds that the split in value between consumer surplus and producer surplus in dis-
parate sectors of the economy is in the range of 20:1 in favor of consumers, including in agriculture and
offshore manufacturing.
10
Sceptics have also labelled as “Hipster Antitrust” the emerging concerns
against the prevailing economic analysis and consumer welfare–based approach to competition
policy.
11
In our view, the debate suffers from a lack of a coherent analytical framework in evaluating the
scope of fairness in the competition policy domain. First, the notion that competition policy should
incorporate considerations of fairness is extremely vague in defining what the term should mean in
practice and in advocating consequential legal and policy changes in the competition policy domain.
Second, arguments dismissing any notion of fairness fail to do justice to the variety of forms that
fairness may take in the competition policy context, possibly neglecting legitimate considerations of
fairness that may be pertinent to the scope and functioning of this area of law.
In this article, we address the scope of fairness in competition policy by disaggregating and
evaluating four distinct notions of fairness that are pertinent to market power in domestic markets:
vertical fairness (between producers and consumers), horizontal fairness on the demand side (between
consumers), horizontal fairness on the supply side (between producers), and procedural fairness (due
process and private enforcement). Not only can the different dimensions of fairness be distinguished
using the categories of supply and demand (fairness between and within supply and demand), but they
(2017); Alfonso Lamadrid de Pablo, Competition Law and Fairness,8J.COMPETITION L. & PRAC. 147 (2017); Lina Khan &
Sandeep Vaheesan, Market Power and Inequality: The Antitrust Counterrevolution and Its Discontents 11 HARV.L.&POLY
REV. 235 (2016); Sean F. Ennis, Pedro Gonzaga, & Chris Pike, Inequality: A Hidden Cost of Market Power (2017), https://
ssrn.com/abstract¼2942791; Jonathan Tepper, The Myth of Capitalism: Monopolies and the Death of Competition (Wiley,
2018). See also Suresh Nadiu, Eric A. Posner, & E. Glen Weyl, Antitrust Remedies for Labour Market Power,HARV. L.R.
(forthcoming); Ioana Marinescu & Herbert Hovenkamp, Anticompetitive Mergers in Labor Markets, 1965 FAC.SCHOLARSHIP
(2018).
3. See Jonathan Baker & Steven Salop, Antitrust, Competition Policy, and Inequality 104 GEO. L.J. 1 (2015). For a different
view, see Daniel A. Crane, Antitrust and Wealth Inequality 101 CORNELL L. REV. 1171 (2016).
4. ANTHONY ATKINSON,INEQUALITY:WHAT CAN BEDONE? (2015).
5. JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ,THE PRICE OF INEQUALITY:HOW TODAYSDIVIDED SOCIETY ENDANGERS OUR FUTURE 338 (2012).
6. Paul Krugman, Robot s and Robber Barons,N.Y.T
IMES, Dec. 10, 2012, http://www.nytimes.com/2 012/12/10/opinion/
krugman-robots-and-robber-barons.html?mcubz¼1; Paul Krugman, Robber Baron Recessions,N.Y.TIMES,Apr.18,
2016, https://www.nytimes.com/2016/04/18/opinion/robber-baron-recessions.html?mcubz¼1.
7. Margrethe Vestager, How Competition Can Build Trust in Societies, TED Talk (Sep. 21, 2017), https:// ec.europa.eu/
commission/commissioners/2014-2019/vestager/announcements/how-competition-can-build-trust-our-societies_en.
8. Herbert J. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Policy and Inequality of Wealth, 1769 FAC.SCHOLARSHIP (2017); Crane, supra note 3.
9. EDWARD CONARD,UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES:WHY EVERYTHING YOUVE BEEN TOLD ABOUT THE ECONOMY ISWRONG (2012).
10. Id. at 38.
11. Competition Policy International, Hipster Antitrust,1ANTITRUST CHRON. (2018).
80 The Antitrust Bulletin 64(1)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT