The Relationship Between Regulatory Pressure and Insurer Risk Taking

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1539-6975.2012.01505.x
AuthorYi‐Hsun Lai,Wen‐Chang Lin,Michael R. Powers
Published date01 June 2014
Date01 June 2014
©
DOI: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2012.01505.x
271
THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN REGULATORY PRESSURE
AND INSURER RISK TAKING
Wen-Chang Lin
Yi-H sun L ai
Michael R. Powers
ABSTRACT
The article examines the risk-taking behavior of property–liability insurers
in the presence of risk-based capital regulation. An option pricing model is
developed to evaluate the expected regulatory cost and predict a nonlinear
relationship between regulatory pressure and insurers’ risk taking. We then
conduct an empirical test using the simultaneous threshold regression. The
result shows that there is a threshold effect of regulatorypressure on insurer
risk taking. Poorly capitalized insurers seem to be aware of their proximity
to regulatory interventions but do not fully respond to the impending reg-
ulatory pressure. This implies either regulatory interventions are not costly
enough or they are too late, or both.
INTRODUCTION
Understanding the risk-taking behavior of financial institutions, including banks and
insurance firms, is important to not only regulators but also claimholders of these
firms because the behavior can substantially affect values of the firms and thus how
the values are distributed between claimholders. A number of theories have been
proposed to explain the behavior in the banking and insurance literature. However,
they often make contradictory predictions regarding the risk-taking behavior of fi-
nancial institutions. For example, the risk-subsidy hypothesis predicts that banks and
insurers will engage in excessive risk taking when deposit insurance for banks or
guarantee funds for insurers are nonrisk based. The reason is that the deficit of de-
posits and insurance policies will be absorbed by government funds when these firms
become insolvent, and thus the firms pay little cost for their high risk taking. When
banks/insurers attempt to increase their risk taking, they can either increase portfolio
risk or lower capital level, or both. Hence, the risk-subsidy hypothesis predicts a neg-
ative relationship between capital and risk. Another stem of theories regarding the
Wen-ChangLin is an associate professor in the Department of Finance, National Chung Cheng
University,Taiwan.Yi-Hsun Lai is an assistant professor in the Department of Finance, National
Yunlin University of Science and Technology, Taiwan. Michael R. Powers is a professor in
the Department of Finance, Tsinghua University, and on leave from the Department of Risk
Management and Insurance, Temple University. Wen-Chang Lin can be contacted via e-mail:
finwcl@ccu.edu.tw.
The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2013, Vol. 81, No. 2, 271–301
272 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE
risk-taking behavior of financial institutions, in contrast, advocates that these firms
will operate in a finite-risk paradigm if relatively large costs can result from high
risk taking. These costs include transaction costs,1agency costs,2bankruptcy costs,3
regulatory costs,4and others.5This class of theories anticipates that financial insti-
tutions will sustain their financial strength by either raising capital when their asset
risk is increasing or lowering asset risk when their capitalization is declining, and
thus predicts that capital and risk levels will be positively correlated. Despite the fact
that these two distinct types of theories have their relative merits, it seems unlikely
that the costs and the benefits resulting from risk taking are mutually exclusive. For
example, if a firm decides to adjust its risk to a lower level, the rationale behind the
change must be that the decrease in the associated costs as a whole is larger than the
decrease in the benefits resulting from government subsidy. The logic of this line of
reasoning leads us to conclude that banks and insurers choose their optimal mix of
capital and risk based upon a trade-off between the associated costs and benefits.
The property–liability (P–L) insurance industry has been characterized by high busi-
ness risk, intense competition, and relatively stringent regulation from governments.
However, in relation to the extensive research on the risk-taking behavior of banks,
there are a small number of studies investigating the risk-taking behavior of insurers.
Cummins and Sommer (1996) find that insurers are likely to restrain their risk taking
due to policyholders’ demand for safety when the protection of guarantee funds is
incomplete. However, Lee et al. (1997) find that the existence of state guarantee funds
generally encourages insurers to increase risk taking. Baranoff and Sager (2002, 2003)
find that capital level and asset risk of life insurers are positively correlated. They
therefore conclude that life insurers overall were operated in a finite-risk paradigm to
curb transaction costs. There have been, nevertheless, relatively few studies devoted
to understanding the extent to which capital regulation can influence insurers’ risk
taking. Tofill the gap, the objective of the study is to examine the association between
regulatory pressure and the risk-taking behavior for P–L insurers.
Similar to what is observed in the banking industry, the risk-based capital (RBC)6
standard adopted in 1994 forms the principal basis for the current solvency
1Transaction-cost economics (see, e.g., Williamson, 1988) posits that financial institutions will
limit their product risks to forestall paying high financing costs, as the cost of debt financing
will increase if they sell risky products.
2The agency theory contends that the separation of management and ownership can lead to
lower risk taking by managers as they do not share residual profits with owners.
3Bankruptcy costs are those such as the cost of liquidating the firm and the loss of franchise
value.
4Regulatory costs have received relatively considerable research attention in the banking lit-
erature (e.g., Shrieves and Dahl, 1992; Jacques and Nigro, 1997; Park, 1997; Ediz et al., 1998;
Aggarwal and Jacques, 2001; Rime, 2001).
5For example, Repullo (2004) contends that risk taking of banks may be associated with the
degree of market competition. When markets are overcompetitive or appear to be monopo-
listic, firms may increase their risk taking. In contrast, under a moderate competitive market,
firms may lower their risk taking to protect their franchise value.
6RBC regulation aims to prevent costly insolvencies by mandating insurers to hold a satis-
factory level of capital. The required capital is determined by a formula-based risk measure
encompassing asset risks, underwriting risks, credit risks, and miscellaneous risks.
REGULATORY PRESSURE AND INSURER RISK TAKING 273
regulation in the insurance industry. RBC regulation is mainly designed to target
problem (i.e., poorly capitalized) insurers and take necessary corrective actions when
RBC ratios of these insurers fall below the required standard. These disciplinary
interventions will affect insurers’ operation and incur high regulatory costs to the in-
surers.7When these regulatory costs exceed the benefits from risk taking, the insurers
would stop taking risky investments. This line of reasoning motivates us to contend
that there can exist a threshold at which insurers alter their risk taking in response to
the cost–benefit trade-off.
Our intention to examine whether risk taking and regulatory pressure arenonlinearly
correlated in the insurance industry is also motivated by two related studies in the
banking literature. Shrieves and Dahl (1992) document that the extent to which RBC
regulation can influence a bank’s risk taking depends on how far the bank’s capital
level is away from the RBC standard. Jacques and Nigro (1997) find that RBC reg-
ulation is effective in controlling banks’ risk taking and particularly that weak and
healthier banks react differently to RBC regulatory pressure, suggesting that the cap-
ital level and the magnitude of regulatory pressure need not correlate in a monotonic
(i.e., linear) manner. Although Shrieves and Dahl (1992) and Jacques and Nigro(1997)
both recognize the nonlinear influence of regulatory pressure on banks’ risk taking in
their studies, they deal with the issue by simply using a dummy variable to partition
banks into two groups depending on whether their capital ratios fall below the explicit
RBC standard. These two studies further find that the influence of RBC regulatory
pressure on the risk-taking behavior of the two bank groups appears asymmetric.
Extending the studies of Shrieves and Dahl (1992) and Jacques and Nigro (1997), we
argue that there is an implicit threshold of regulatory pressure at which an insurer
will change its risk taking and the threshold, if any exists, does not necessarily equate
to the explicit RBC standard.
The study thus proposes a new research scheme to address the nonlinear relationship
between regulatory pressure and risk taking for insurers. We first develop an option
pricing model to illustrate how regulatory pressure is related to insurers’ risk taking.
To the best of our knowledge, this makes our study the first to apply the option
pricing model to the insurance field in such a context. The theoretical model shows
that insurers will alter their risk taking at a regulatory-pressure threshold where
savings in the expected regulatory cost are equal to reductions in the put option value
expropriated from guarantee funds. The existence of such an implicit threshold in
fact predicts a nonlinear relationship between regulatory pressure and risk taking.
At the second stage of the study,we use a simultaneous threshold-regression model8
to examine whether insurers’ risk-taking behavior is nonlinear and to evaluate the
effectiveness of capital regulation in terms of whether the trigger point of the RBC
standard for disciplinary action is adequate and how costly the disciplinary action is
to insurers. Our study is also the first to apply simultaneous threshold regression to
this area of research. We believe that the threshold-regression model is best suited for
the purpose of the study.It can ascertain whether a threshold effect exists and provide
7Recently, Cheng and Weiss (2012) find that the ability of the RBC ratio in predicting insurer
insolvencies is not consistent over time.
8Threshold regression was originally developed by Hansen (1999) and simultaneous threshold
regression was recently developed by Caner and Hansen (2004).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT