THE PRICE‐TAKER EFFECT ON THE VALUATION OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTIONS

Date01 February 2014
Published date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12027
THE PRICETAKER EFFECT ON THE VALUATION OF EXECUTIVE
STOCK OPTIONS
TungHsiao Yang
National Chung Hsing University
Don M. Chance
Louisiana State University
Abstract
Because of vesting requirements and the absence of liquidity, executive stock options are
valued at less, and often far less, than BlackScholesMerton values. We argue that this
view assumes the subtle condition that option holders are price takers and therefore
cannot inuence the payoffs of their options, an assumption that clearly contradicts the
very reason for granting options. We build a model to incorporate the executives effort
and perception of his quality, private beliefs, and condence to show that these options
are worth considerably more than previously believed and under some conditions even
more than BlackScholesMerton values.
JEL Classification: G34, M52
I. Introduction
Traditional nancial models almost always assume that no investor can inuence the price
of an asset by trading. Investors are said to be price takers. This assumption, so common
that it is rarely even mentioned, is second nature in models of competitive markets. The
markets for publicly traded options are generally competitive enough to support this
assumption, and as such, the BlackScholesMerton model and almost all of its variants
assume that all market participants are price takers.
There is a history, both in research and in practice, of using the BlackScholes
Merton model, with some adjustments, to value executive stock options. Thus, doing so
implicitly assumes that executives are price takers. Because the options are awarded in
part to incentivize executives, the notion that an executive is a price taker clearly belies a
critical characteristic of these options.
A signicant body of published papers shows that executives value their options
at substantially less than BlackScholesMerton values. Such a conclusion is a natural
result of penalizing the options for their lack of liquidity. Awarding executives nancial
This paper was presented at the Financial Management Association Europe, Southern Finance Association,
and Northern Finance Association meetings, and a faculty seminar at the University of Oklahoma. The authors thank
Jean Canil, Andrea Heuson, WeiLing Song, Cliff Stephens, John Wald, Adam Yore, David Koslowsky, and Ivan
Brick for comments and suggestions.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXXVII, No. 1 Pages 2754 Spring 2014
27
© 2014 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
assets over which they have no control of the payoffs and that they cannot sell will
certainly cause the executives to value those assets at less than would other investors who
similarly have no control over the outcomes but who are free to sell at will.
Accurate valuation of executive stock options is an important issue, as it affects
our understanding of how options incentivize executives. The literature acknowledges
that the executive and the company do not hold mirror images of each others position.
1
The companys cost of the option can be substantially different from the executives value
of the option. If an executive has a different opinion of the value of his options than the
company believes the options are worth, it will not award the proper number of options to
incentivize the executive. As noted, under traditional models of executive stock option
valuation, the option value tends to lie well below the cost to the company, but as also
noted, these models assume the executive is a price taker. Recognizing the fact that the
executive can inuence the payoff of the option, it follows that the executive is likely to
have a higher opinion of the value of the option than he would if he had no inuence. As
such, the companys belief of how the executive values the option would be well below
what the executive actually believes. Failing to recognize this fact could lead the company
to award more options than necessary to incentivize the executive and therefore would
raise the cost to the company. Indeed, the large numbers of options seemingly awarded to
executives may well be driven by the belief that executives value these options at much
less than they really do.
In this article we reexamine the traditional utilitybased approach of executive
stock option valuation and remove the pricetaker assumption by incorporating the effect
of the executives perception of his effort, ability, and condence on his private valuation
of the options. It shows that these factors lead executives to value options at far more than
suggested by traditional models and that under some circumstances, at more than Black
ScholesMerton values. We also examine how incorporation of these effects inuences
the executives decision to exercise early.
II. Previous Research
A large body of literature exists on the valuation of executive stock options. Probably the
most widely referenced work is Hall and Murphy (2002), who model a riskaverse
executive holding a stock option and stock in the rm. They set up an expected utility
maximization problem in which the executive determines the certainty equivalent value of
the option as the cashthat would be accepted in lieu of the option. The executiveis assumed
to be unable to sell the option, but may, after the vesting day, choose to exercise it early.
There are numerous extensions of the HallMurphy model, but all are generally framed
around the idea that a riskadverseexecutive holds an illiquid option with limited ability to
diversify within a moderateto extremely high degree of risk concentration in his portfolio.
2
1
For an excellent discussion of this distinction, see Carpenter (1998, pp. 13132).
2
For related and different approaches, see Lambert, Larcker, and Verrecchia (1991), Carpenter (1998),
Henderson (2005), Kulatilaka and Marcus (1994), Cai and Vijh (2005), Detemple and Sundaresan (1999),
Meulbroek (2001), and Ingersoll (2006).
28 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT