The Potential Role for Emission Offsets in Climate Change Policy

AuthorJoseph E. Aldy
PositionEconomist on the faculty at the Harvard Kennedy School
Pages15-15
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 2021 | 15
Reprinted by permission from The Environmental Forum®, November/December 2021.
Copyright © 2021, Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, D.C. www.eli.org.
An Economic Perspective
Governments, big corporations,
and universities have recently
issued ambitious greenhouse
gas emission pledges. e European
Union and a number of its largest
member-states have legislated net-
zero emissions by 2050. e state of
California set a goal of net-zero emis-
sions by 2045, Microsoft aims to be
carbon-negative by 2030, and Har-
vard University has committed to be-
ing fossil fuel-neutral by 2026.
Common to each of these goals will
be the use of emission osets — emis-
sion reductions outside of a govern-
ment’s jurisdiction or the footprint of a
company or a university. ese osets
would make up for the residual emis-
sions for that entity — the dicult-to-
eliminate uses of fossil fuels in some
specialized industrial
purposes, aviation,
building heating, etc.
So long as these emis-
sions osets equal or
exceed the residual
emissions for that en-
tity, then its net emis-
sions would be equal to zero in the rst
case or even less in the second.
Emission osets have long served as
a exible, market-oriented approach to
implement environmental goals. Since
the 1980s, new emission sources can
be built in areas with poor air quality
if they oset their emissions at exist-
ing sources. Starting in the early 1990s,
developers can drain a wetland if they
enhance or create new wetlands nearby.
And osets have played a role in imple-
menting UN climate change agree-
ments.
e 1997 Kyoto Protocol estab-
lished the Clean Development Mecha-
nism, where a project in a developing
country could generate emission re-
duction credits that could be used by a
developed country for compliance with
its emission target. For example, Ja-
pan’s emissions exceeded its Kyoto tar-
get, but it oset its emissions above its
target through the purchase of CDM
credits. e European Union also per-
mitted emission sources covered by its
Emission Trading System to use CDM
credits as a compliance strategy in lieu
of emission allowances. More recently,
emission osets have been used by
sources covered by the California car-
bon dioxide cap-and-trade program.
Emission osets may lower the cost
of attaining ambitious emission goals
by giving businesses covered by a cap-
and-trade or regulatory program the
exibility to invest in emission-cutting
projects beyond their footprint. Such
programs may create incentives to
drive emission reductions in sectors of
the economy or countries of the world
where the political economy precludes
emission regulation. Examples include
the U.S. agricultural
sector and developing
countries under the
Kyoto Protocol. As
more and more com-
panies adopt net-zero
emission goals, the de-
mand for emission o-
sets could increase, with some estimat-
ing a market size as large as $50 billion
a year by 2030.
e potential for osets, however,
must confront a few key implementa-
tion challenges. e estimated emis-
sions reduced, avoided, or sequestered
associated with any given oset project
reects a comparison with a hypotheti-
cal counterfactual, such as a no-project
baseline. is is intended to show that
the emission reductions are additional
or incremental; i.e., that they would
not have happened otherwise.
In practice, this is dicult to dem-
onstrate. ere are cases where oset
project developers gamed the rules,
such as CDM projects in China to
reduce HFC-23, a potent greenhouse
gas. e revenue from selling CDM
credits made it economic for develop-
ers to build HFC-23 manufacturing
capacity for the primary purpose of
shutting it down in order to generate
emission reduction credits.
In other cases, there are legitimate
questions about the permanence of
the estimated emission reductions. For
example, forest conservation and aor-
estation programs may remove carbon
dioxide from the air and store it within
woody biomass and soils. If these for-
ests are cut down or burn down later,
however, then the sequestered carbon
could be emitted, eectively eliminat-
ing the climate benets of the original
project.
Even for well-intended projects,
there may be a form of market leak-
age that reduces the emission-cutting
benets for those projects. Conserving
forests to sequester carbon may increase
the incentive to cut forests elsewhere to
meet lumber demand. Building a wind
farm in lieu of a coal-red power plant
may enable existing coal-red plants to
operate longer by reducing demand for
coal. Installing solar may appear addi-
tional today, but if public policy evolves
— such as through a high carbon tax
or a regulation mandating solar — then
this project should not be considered
additional under these future policies.
Providing cost-eective ways to cut
emissions will be critical for countries
and companies to secure durable po-
litical support along the journey to at-
taining their ambitious net-zero emis-
sion goals. Osets can play a key role,
so long as transparency and rules can
minimize the prospect that this ap-
proach undermines the environmental
integrity of net-zero goals.
e Potential Role for Emission
Osets in Climate Change Policy
Cost-effective ways to
cut emissions will be
critical for countries
and companies
Joseph E. Aldy is an economist
on the facult y at the Harva rd Ken-
nedy School . You can contact hi m at
Joseph_Aldy@hks.harvard.edu.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT