The Politics of Temporary Work Deregulation in Europe

Date01 September 2013
DOI10.1177/0032329213493754
Published date01 September 2013
AuthorTim Vlandas
Subject MatterArticles
Politics & Society
41(3) 425 –460
© 2013 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0032329213493754
pas.sagepub.com
Article
The Politics of Temporary
Work Deregulation in Europe:
Solving the French Puzzle
Tim Vlandas
European Institute, London School of Economics, London, UK
Abstract
Temporary work has expanded in the last three decades with adverse implications
for inequalities. Because temporary workers are a constituency that is unlikely
to impose political costs, governments often choose to reduce temporary work
regulations. While most European countries have indeed implemented such reforms,
France went in the opposite direction, despite having both rigid labor markets and
high unemployment. My argument to solve this puzzle is that where replaceability is
high, workers in permanent and temporary contracts have overlapping interests, and
governments choose to regulate temporary work to protect permanent workers. In
turn, replaceability is higher where permanent workers’ skills are general and wage
coordination is low. Logistic regression analysis of the determinants of replaceability—
and how this affects governments’ reforms of temporary work regulations—supports
my argument. Process tracing of French reforms also confirm that the left has
tightened temporary work regulations to compensate for the high replaceability.
Keywords
insider-outsider, temporary work, employment protection legislation, replaceability,
labor market reform.
Corresponding Author:
Tim Vlandas, European Institute, London School of Economics, Houghton Street, WC2A 2AE, London,
UK.
Email: t.r.vlandas@lse.ac.uk
493754PAS41310.1177/0032329213493754Politics & SocietyVlandas
research-article2013
426 Politics & Society 41(3)
A growing literature documents the increased dualization of welfare state policies and
employment protection in Europe.1 Welfare states have been reformed in ways that
reduce the entitlements, protection, and welfare of outsiders, understood here as pre-
carious and unemployed workers.2 The literature argues that governments choose to
preserve existing institutional arrangements for insiders while reducing the entitle-
ments and employment protection of outsiders. In this paper I consider the case of
temporary workers, which represents a good case of outsiders. The expansion of tem-
porary work also has political implications, as these workers have distinct political
preferences3 and distinct preferences for labor-market policies.4 More importantly,
like other labor-market outsiders, temporary workers have lower electoral turnout,
raising the risk of an increasingly large segment of the population being politically
excluded.5
The emergence of temporary work also has wide-ranging implications for inequal-
ity. Besides having lower objective and subjective employment security,6 temporary
workers also earn comparatively less, report lower job satisfaction, and have less
access to training.7 In Europe, temporary workers earn, on average, 20 percent less
than their permanent counterparts and the pay gap remains when controlling for differ-
ences in seniority, skills, and sector.8 The Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development (OECD) estimates that the pay penalty of working with a temporary
contract may be as large as 25 percent when controlling for gender, age, working
hours, and education.9
As a result, temporary workers are twice as likely to be in poverty than permanent
workers (12 percent compared to 6 percent).10 Wage inequality therefore increases as
the regulation of temporary work is reduced and the employment protection of regular
workers is raised.11 Temporary workers are also less often eligible for unemployment
benefits and social insurance,12 and they raise particularly acute challenges for private
insurance systems.13 Being employed on a temporary work contract also has adverse
effects on health.14
To the extent that temporary work is not evenly distributed among different groups
of the population, these contracts also exacerbate preexisting inequalities between
workers of different gender, age, and educational levels.15 Women are more likely to
be temporary workers, thereby increasing gender inequality.16 Youth are particularly
affected with 42 percent being on temporary contracts in the EU27.17 More than 20
percent of those with lower levels of education are in the temporary work sector, twice
as much as for those with higher education.18 Last but not least, among low-income
workers, the pay gap between temporary and permanent workers is even larger.19
The evolution of Employment Protection Legislation (EPL) for temporary workers
in the European Union (EU) therefore has important implications for inequality and
for the politics of labor-market policies. Despite the adverse consequences of tempo-
rary work for inequality, poverty, and economic efficiency, the ensuing politics of
temporary work regulations entail a particular challenge for governments. Specifically,
it is particularly difficult for governments to increase the protection of temporary
workers because they are unlikely to impose political costs on governments that
neglect their interests. To the extent that governments need to choose which group to
Vlandas 427
protect or to focus on, they are unlikely to choose temporary workers. Thus, temporary
work should be construed as a case of the political challenges that governments face
to protect politically weaker groups.
Most governments have indeed reduced the EPL for temporary workers in the last
two decades (see Table 1). There are three important exceptions to this trend: the
United Kingdom, Ireland, and France. Both the United Kingdom and Ireland are lib-
eral market economies, with very flexible labor markets20 and comparatively few tem-
porary workers. Though they have slightly tightened the EPL for temporary workers,
the resulting level in 2007 was still among the lowest in Western Europe.
The case of France is much more puzzling, as its EPL for temporary workers in
2007 was the highest in Western Europe. This strongly suggests that France has been
moving in the opposite direction from other European counties. Whereas left-wing
parties in other EU countries have deregulated temporary work when in power, the left
in France has repeatedly increased regulation of temporary work. This is puzzling
because France has all the conditions that the literature identifies for reductions of
outsiders’ status, such as lower EPL for temporary workers, to occur. Regular workers
in permanent employment—insiders—are well protected. Unions have neither tempo-
rary workers among their members,21 nor are they strong enough to protect them.
France also had as much “need” as other countries (e.g., unemployment, trade open-
ness) to deregulate temporary work.
Table 1. EPL for temporary workers and size of temporary work sector in the EU.
EPL temporary
workers
Temporary workers
(share of total dependent employees)
Countries 2007-1985 2007 2007 2007 - earliest year Reference year
France 0.57 3.63 15.08 11.74 1983
Ireland 0.38 0.63 8.05 1.94 1983
UK 0.13 0.38 5.85 0.35 1983
Austria 0 1.5 8.89 2.9 1995
Finland 0 1.88 15.96 -2.38 1997
Spain -0.25 3.5 31.66 16.07 1987
Portugal -0.63 2.75 22.36 7.96 1986
Netherlands -1.19 1.19 18.08 12.26 1983
Greece -1.62 3.13 10.88 -5.36 1983
Denmark -1.75 1.38 9.05 -3.4 1984
Belgium -2 2.63 8.65 3.26 1983
Sweden -2.45 1.63 17.45 2.85 1997
Germany -2.5 1.25 14.64 4.68 1984
Italy -3.5 1.88 13.21 6.6 1983
Source: OECD statistic website, own calculations.
Note: EPL for temporary workers is a composite index created by the OECD.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT