The Politics of Innovation Policy: Building Israel’s “Neo-developmental” State

AuthorErez Maggor
Published date01 December 2021
Date01 December 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0032329220945527
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329220945527
Politics & Society
2021, Vol. 49(4) 451 –487
© The Author(s) 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0032329220945527
journals.sagepub.com/home/pas
Article
The Politics of Innovation
Policy: Building Israel’s
“Neo-developmental”
State
Erez Maggor
New York University
Abstract
This article contributes to an emerging literature on the “neo” or “entrepreneurial”
developmental state that emphasizes the role of innovation policy in promoting the
structural transformation of industry. It finds further evidence that supports this
approach and advances it by making two unique contributions. First, it highlights
an essential yet underappreciated feature of contemporary innovation policy: the
state’s capacity to condition public assistance and discipline private firms that do not
adhere to government guidelines. These capacities are necessary to guarantee that
the benefits of public investment in innovation—the social and economic spillovers—
are not appropriated by private actors but shared more broadly within society.
Second, it highlights that politics—reflected in the relations between innovation
agencies and key social actors—represents an important causal factor in both the
formation and subsequent transformation of these institutional capacities. These
points are illustrated through a historical analysis of a crucial case: the state-led
development of Israel’s thriving high-tech sector.
Keywords
innovation, Israel, developmental state, policy, discipline
Corresponding Author:
Erez Maggor, New York University, 295 Lafayette St. 4th Floor, New York, NY 10012, USA.
Email: erez.maggor@nyu.edu
945527PASXXX10.1177/0032329220945527Politics & SocietyMaggor
research-article2020
452 Politics & Society 49(4)
Industrial policy is back on the political agenda. From Germany’s “Industrie 4.0”
to “Made in China 2025,” policymakers worldwide are advancing ambitious
innovation policies that aim to transform industry, foster the development of
cutting-edge technologies, and promote inclusive growth. These policies also seek
to harness innovation to address formidable social and global challenges, including
the demographic aging crisis, widening economic inequality, and adverse climate
change. Such policies call for a wide range of measures often identified with a
“neo” or “entrepreneurial” developmental state.1 They include targeted government
investment in R&D and training, support for marketing and exporting, networking
and brokerage services, and building of facilities and science parks. They follow a
period in which such proactive state targeting was avoided for fear it would encourage
rent-seeking behavior, waste taxpayer money, and distort market competition and
resource allocation. Yet a growing literature on innovation has found that, in contrast
to Washington Consensus policy prescriptions, such bold and transformative strategies
have in fact been essential for the economic success of some of the world’s most
innovative economies. That was the case not only for developing nations such as
Korea, Taiwan, Ireland, Finland, and most recently China2 but also for advanced
economies such as Germany and even the United States.3
This article finds evidence that supports the state-led account of innovation and
advances the literature by making two specific contributions. The first contribution is
to highlight a crucial, yet underappreciated, feature of contemporary industrial strat-
egy: the state’s capacity to condition public assistance on the fulfillment of specific
terms and obligations and enforce discipline when private firms do not adhere to gov-
ernment guidelines. I find that, much like the catch-up developmental state of the
postwar period, the effectiveness of innovation policies has depended on these specific
capacities. Whereas state assistance was historically tied to maintaining strict perfor-
mance standards, mainly in the realm of export promotion, contemporary innovation-
targeted strategies require conditioning assistance on the domestic commercialization
of state-sponsored innovation.4 As will be discussed at length below, these capacities
are necessary in order to guarantee that the social and economic “spillovers” produced
by the state’s investment in innovation are not appropriated by private actors but rather
distributed more broadly within the domestic economy.
The second contribution involves returning to the fundamental debate about the
role of politics—reflected in the relations between the state’s developmental agencies
and key societal actors—in development. With some notable exceptions, such as
recent work by Richard Doner and Ben Schneider on the political economy of devel-
opment, the scholarship on innovation has not paid much attention to how state action
is constrained (or enabled) by its relationship with various social groups.5 By incorpo-
rating an analysis of the politics of policy formation and institutional change, I high-
light that politics represents a key causal factor in both the implementation and
potential transformation of innovation policy. After all, the political sphere is where
the institutions that govern policy are formed and potentially reformed.
To illustrate these points, I offer a critical exploration of a crucial case,6 previ-
ously regarded as a “neo-developmental” state and commonly referenced in
Maggor 453
the literature on innovation policy: the state-led development of Israel’s high-tech
sector.7 First, I demonstrate the central role that conditionality and state discipline
played in the success of Israel’s thriving innovation economy. Next, I trace these
institutional capacities to the emergence of a political coalition that was formed by
Israel’s leading developmental agency and included key members of industry,
finance, and labor as well as former military elites and leading entrepreneurial sci-
entists and engineers. Whereas the failure to build similar upgrading coalitions
served as the main political obstacle to development efforts elsewhere, in Israel this
coalition underpinned the state’s efforts to restructure industry in the direction of a
knowledge-based economy and played a pivotal role in the successful implementa-
tion of the state’s innovation policies.8 Finally, I depict how changes within this
coalition due to the appearance of Israel’s venture capital industry—a powerful new
actor with distinctly different policy preferences—eventually eroded vital institu-
tional capacities and led to significantly fewer public rewards. Thus, in addition to
enhancing our understanding of the role of conditionality and discipline in contem-
porary industrial policy, this study also contributes to growing debates on the “polit-
ical economy of innovation,”9 as well as to the robust literature on the role of politics
in institutional change.10
The article begins with a review of the relevant literature. This section highlights
why innovation-led development brings about unique challenges requiring that the
state condition its assistance and gain the capacity to discipline uncooperative firms. I
follow with a historical illustration using the case of Israel. I begin with an outline of
the relevant historical background and then proceed to the main empirical sections.
Here, I outline the unique institutional capacities of Israel’s Office of the Chief
Scientist—a “Schumpeterian developmental agency” that has received international
acclaim for stimulating the growth of Israel’s thriving high-tech industry.11 Next, I
discuss the political origins of these capacities and outline how they have changed
over time. I do so by leveraging an in-case comparative analysis demonstrating how a
shift in the original upgrading coalition worked to erode the central pillars of Israel’s
original innovation policy and how those changes, in turn, have had a negative impact
on developmental outcomes.
From “Catch-Up” to “Innovation-Based” Development
The Catch-Up Developmental State: Goals, Strategies, and Capacities
Starting in the 1980s, investigations into the “miraculous” economic success of a
number of East Asian countries—first Japan, later South Korea, Taiwan, and
Singapore—challenged the widespread commonsense of the Washington
Consensus. That scholarship demonstrated that the unprecedented success of those
newly industrialized countries rested not in their commitment to free market prin-
ciples but rather in their reliance on a comprehensive industrial program imple-
mented by a developmental state. Such industrial policies generated an economic
transformation by targeting investment in select industrial sectors and fostering

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT