The Politics of Dispossession

DOI10.1177/0032329213493751
Published date01 September 2013
Date01 September 2013
AuthorMichael Levien
Subject MatterArticles
Politics & Society
41(3) 351 –394
© 2013 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0032329213493751
pas.sagepub.com
Article
The Politics of Dispossession:
Theorizing India’s “Land
Wars”
Michael Levien
Johns Hopkins University
Abstract
While struggles over land dispossession have recently proliferated across the
developing world and become particularly significant in India, this paper argues that
existing theories of political agency do not capture the specificity of the politics of
dispossession. Based on two years of ethnographic research on anti-dispossession
movements across rural India, the paper argues that the dispossession of land
creates a specific kind of politics, distinct not just from labor politics, but also
from various other forms of peasant politics that have been theorized in the social
sciences. It illustrates how the process of land dispossession itself shapes the
targets, strategy and tactics, organization, social composition, goals, and ideologies
of anti-dispossession struggles. It concludes with reflections on why land conflicts
are less easily institutionalized than labor conflicts and may therefore constitute
a significantly disruptive force in the emerging centers of global capitalism for the
foreseeable future.
Keywords
accumulation by dispossession, land grabs, social movements, agrarian change, peasant
politics, Polanyi, India
Corresponding Author:
Michael Levien, Department of Sociology, Johns Hopkins University, 533 Mergenthaler Hall, 3400 N.
Charles St., Baltimore, MD 21218, USA.
Email: levien@jhu.edu
493751PAS41310.1177/0032329213493751Politics & SocietyLevien
research-article2013
352 Politics & Society 41(3)
There is a growing recognition that frameworks of political agency premised on the
position of wage laborers in capitalist production do not capture many of the most
significant political struggles against neoliberal capitalism. In many parts of the world,
labor struggles have been overshadowed by social movements, insurgencies, and
resistances that do not originate from the proletariat—strictly speaking—and that are
fighting not exploitation but innumerable forms of dispossession of private and com-
mon wealth: what Harvey has called “accumulation by dispossession.”1 Rural land has
become a major locus of such dispossession in many developing countries, bringing
the state and metropolitan capitalists into direct confrontation with rural agricultural-
ists. In India, the use of eminent domain and other state powers to expropriate land
from farmers for increasingly privatized industrial, infrastructural, and real estate proj-
ects has, in recent years, generated widespread agrarian uprisings, popularly dubbed
“land wars.” While so-called land wars have moved to the center of Indian politics and
are attracting greater scholarly interest globally, this paper argues that existing theories
of political agency do not capture the specificity of the politics of dispossession. Based
on a broad mapping of anti-dispossession movements across India, this paper advances
some parameters for such a theory.
Although the dispossession of agrarian land has long been an aspect of capitalist
development in most parts of the world, its economic and political significance appears
to be generally increasing. This renewed significance appears to be global, and “land
grabs” are now attracting significant scholarly attention in Africa,2 Southeast Asia,3
and Latin America.4 However, it is arguably in the two rapidly growing countries that
together contain 45 percent of the world’s rural population that land struggles have
reached the greatest scale and political explosiveness.5 In China, scholars estimate that
between 50 and 66 million people were dispossessed for various kinds of development
projects between 1980 and 2002, and that land grabs now constitute the single largest
source of peasant protest,6 and possibly of “mass incidents” more generally.7 The
efforts of local governments to cheaply acquire farmland for private developers has
triggered a series of farmer protests, including high-profile clashes in the villages of
Wukan in 2011 and Shangpu in 2013, which appear to be drawing inspiration from
each other. These proliferating land struggles have forced Chinese leaders to pay some
obeisance to protecting farmers’ land rights,8 and prompted limited efforts to rein in
the land brokering of local governments.9
In India, the accelerating dispossession of land for private investment in the post-
liberalization period, combined with a relatively open democracy, has made the land
question perhaps even more politically consequential than in China. While it is esti-
mated that 60 million people have been displaced from their land for development
projects since independence in 1947, the rate of dispossession has by all accounts
increased after liberalization in the early 1990s.10 Its character, moreover, has changed
as Special Economic Zones (SEZs), high-tech cities, real estate, and privatized infra-
structure have joined dams, mining, heavy industry, and commercial forestry as causes
for dispossessing peasants. Since 2005, privately developed and real-estate driven
Special Economic Zones have become the epicenters of “land wars,” with farmers
across India refusing to give land for them. In 2007, India’s land wars boiled over
Levien 353
when fourteen farmers in Nandigram, West Bengal, were massacred, with many more
raped and severely injured, for refusing to give their land for a petrochemical SEZ
promoted by an Indonesian conglomerate. The resulting public outcry catapulted land
dispossession to the center of Indian politics, forcing the central government to limit
land acquisition for SEZs and to introduce amendments to the Land Acquisition Act
(LAA). It also contributed directly to the eventual defeat of the communist Left Front
government that had ruled West Bengal for thirty-four years. And Nandigram was only
the tip of the iceberg.
Across India, farmers have been opposing the efforts of state governments to forc-
ibly transfer their land to private companies. Most surprisingly, they have started to
win in an unprecedented fashion. Farmers have effectively stopped the two largest
proposed SEZs in India (promoted by Reliance Industries near Gurgaon and Mumbai),
all of the SEZs in Goa, and four in Maharasthra. Many more, in all parts of India, are
stuck in land acquisition purgatory. India’s largest proposed Foreign Direct Investment
ever—the twelve megaton POSCO Steel SEZ to be built in coastal Orissa—has been
stalled since 2005 due to fierce resistance by local forest cultivators. The factory that
was to produce Tata Motors’ flagship Nano car had to be relocated from West Bengal
to Gujarat in the face of a strong protest movement by local farmers with the support
of an opposition party.11 In Orissa, resistance by indigenous (adivasi) groups to having
their mountain turned into a bauxite mine for London-based Vedanta forced the central
government to cancel the project.
Although the government keeps no record of these land struggles, by the late 2000s
they were clearly endemic across most of India. While several dozen of them have
achieved a relatively high profile, daily reports in Indian newspapers suggest that their
numbers are easily in the hundreds (Figure 1 illustrates the locations of those that will
be discussed in this paper). The relatively politicized struggles are, moreover, under-
lain by widespread legal opposition to routine government land acquisition. It is not
just that protest is increasing as the scale of dispossession increases; also farmers
appear to be responding more aggressively to being dispossessed for private corpora-
tions under India’s neoliberal growth model than they did to public sector projects in
the period of state-led development.12 With India’s liberalized growth model depen-
dent on the state’s ability to make large tracts of land available to private investors,13
this increasing noncompliance of farmers is now seen as a critical bottleneck for eco-
nomic development.14 Land acquisition has become, in the words of Prime Minister
Manhoman Singh, a “very sensitive” issue that has exposed a contradiction between
the land requirements of India’s liberalized growth model and the exigencies of elec-
toral democracy.15
To assess the long-term significance of this contradiction, we need to better under-
stand the politics of dispossession. David Harvey’s framework of “accumulation by
dispossession” provides a starting point. By freeing Marx’s “primitive accumulation”
from its narrow role in the transition between modes of production, Harvey has created
a versatile concept that is better able to capture diverse forms of contemporary dispos-
session that emanate from, rather than create the preconditions for, advanced capital-
ism. Harvey makes a strong case that Marxists have focused too exclusively on the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT