The Political Economy of Confucian Harmony: A Xunzian Vision

Published date01 March 2019
Date01 March 2019
AuthorSungmoon Kim
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12269
The Political Economy of Confucian
Harmony: A Xunzian Vision
By Sungmoon Kim*
AbStrAct. A global market economy of pure instrumental rationality
now poses a growing threat, jeopardizing common citizenship, the
capacity for human flourishing, and harmony between humans and
nature. Growing skepticism about the sustainability of market
capitalism and its moral legitimacy propels us to search for a new
economic model in which humans are no longer held hostage to the
unbridled pursuit of self-interest and limitless possession at the
expense of the well-being of others and nature and that attempts to
overcome the old conflict between capitalism and socialism. We can
call this alternative model “moral economy,” an economic system that
reconciles private interests with the public good broadly construed.
In this article I reconstruct the Confucian ideal of moral economy by
paying close attention to Xunzi’s ethical and political thought. Xunzi,
one of the key classical Confucians, stipulates the threshold of
sufficiency by extending the ruler’s care to the most destitute of
society as well as giving moral priority to their basic needs without
dismissing the foundational importance of individual merit and
contribution. Rejecting both pure economic meritocracy and dogmatic
egalitarianism, Xunzian Confucianism aims to create a political
economy of harmony where various distributive values (need,
equality, and merit, among other things) each have their own place.
Introduct ion
It is generally held among economists that the economy is categor-
ically independent of the ethico-religious tradition or moral system
American Jour nal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 78, No. 2 (March , 2019).
DOI: 10 .1111/ajes.122 69
© 2019 American Journa l of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
*Professor of political theory and director of the Center for East Asian and Comparative
Philosophy, Department of Public Policy, City University of Hong Kong. PhD in political
science, University of Maryland, College Park. Author of three books.Current work in
progress: Theorizing Confucian Virtue Politics: The Political Philosophy of Mencius and
Xunzi. Email: sungmkim@cityu.edu.hk
494 The American Journal of Economics and Sociology
in which a political community is embedded. In fact, many econ-
omists strongly believe that economics is a value-neutral academic
discipline precisely in the sense that it is singularly concerned with
material interest, maximization of self-interest, rational choice, and
quantifiable human transactions in the market. Libertarian or neo-lib-
eral economists go even further. They claim that as the epitome of
instrumental rationality, the economy ought to be separated from
the ideational (cultural, religious, or ethical) aspect of human life,
which according to Weber (1958: 280) generates an interest of its
own called “ideal interest” as an authoritative determinant of material
interest. Those same economists also believe the economy should
be separated from state intervention as much as possible, based on
the belief that economic transactions are most effective as well as
fair when minimally regulated by the state. For them, the state is
frequently guided improperly by paternalistic purposes, distributive
aims, and political projects, all of which are at odds with an uninhib-
ited exercise of human rationality, rights, and freedoms (Hayek 2007;
Friedman 1962). Neither hinged by a moral system nor encumbered
by politics, the economy creates its own distinctive and purely mer-
it-based sphere of distribution outside of both the state and civil soci-
ety, namely, the market. Not surprisingly, little effort has been made in
contemporary economics and social sciences in general to investigate
the complex relationship between economy, morality, and politics, or
how the economy is nested in the inextricable nexus between moral-
ity and politics.
Traditionally, however, East Asian philosophical traditions were not
oriented toward a belief in self-interest, valorized in rationalist terms.
Nor did they uphold the moral autonomy of the market as the realm
of economic transaction as opposed to the state. Finally, and most
importantly, those traditions did not separate the economy from the
overarching ethical system in which both state and economy were
believed to be nested. Perhaps it is due to their strong tendency to
dismiss the moral value of self-interest or economic utility that East
Asians “failed” to produce a modern capitalist system. That is, they
did not create a system undergirded by pure economic rationality
that, in the West, resulted in possessive individualism, rights-based
liberalism, and liberal constitutionalism.1 Confucianism has been

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT