THE MONETARY ENVIRONMENT AND LONG‐RUN REVERSALS IN STOCK RETURNS

AuthorGerald R. Jensen,Luis Garcia‐Feijoo
Date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12026
Published date01 February 2014
THE MONETARY ENVIRONMENT AND LONGRUN REVERSALS
IN STOCK RETURNS
Luis GarciaFeijoo
Florida Atlantic University
Gerald R. Jensen
Northern Illinois University
Abstract
Previous research attributes longrun reversals to investor overreaction or taxmotivated
trading; we offer an alternative explanation based on the monetary environment. Prices
rebound for stocks that have performed poorly over the past several years (losers);
however, the rebound occurs only during expansive monetary conditions. Winners only
reverse course when monetary conditions are restrictive. Past research shows that the
threefactor model explains longrun stock reversals; we show that the monetary
environment plays an instrumental role in the observation. Finally, we show that reversal
patterns are closely linked to both the monetary environment and a rms level of
nancial constraints.
JEL Classification: G12, G32
I. Introduction
Over the past two decades, there has been increasing debate surrounding the longrun
reversal that has been identied in stock returns. The longrun reversal pattern rst
garnered signicant academic interest when DeBondt and Thaler (1985) observed that
stocks with a prolonged period of poor performance, or loser stocks,subsequently
outperformed winnersby an average of 31.9% over the next ve years. They attribute
this observation to overreaction, whereby investors become overly pessimistic about
stocks that are performing poorly and overly optimistic about stocks exhibiting superior
performance. A consequence of investor overreaction is that price reversals occur for
losers and winners as investors ultimately discover their opinions were too extreme.
Subsequently, researchers have advanced alternative explanations for the longrun
reversal pattern; these explanations rely on either rational, economic investor behavior or
investor trading decisions that are based on irrational views.
The authors acknowledge helpful comments received from an associate editor, an anonymous referee, and
Werner DeBondt, Richard DeFusco, Sanjay Deshmukh, Art Durnev, Keith Gamble, Jon Garnkel, John Geppert,
Wei Li, Jeff Madura, Amrita Nain, Manferd Peterson, Yiming Qian, Ashish Tiwari, Emre Unlu, Anand Vijh, Tong
Yao, and Tom Zorn. In addition, the paper beneted from comments received from seminar participants at the
University of Iowa, DePaul University, the University of NebraskaLincoln, Northern Illinois University, and at the
meetings of the 2012 Financial Management Association (Atlanta, GA). All errors and omissions are our own.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXXVII, No. 1 Pages 325 Spring 2014
3
© 2014 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
The explanation we offer falls most clearly into the category of rational,
economic behavior by investors. Departing from the traditional literature, our explanation
focuses on time variation in risk and risk premia. Recent theoretical and empirical
evidence suggests that stock return expectations are affected by time variation in the
funding conditions for investors and rms (e.g., Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2009; Jensen
and Moorman 2010). This research suggests that improved funding reduces risk aversion
for market makers and speculators and results in greater market liquidity.
Gertler and Gilchrist (1994) contend that small rms, due to their limited access
to funds, face greater nancial constraints, which makes them more sensitive to variations
in credit conditions. Thorbecke (1997) and Jensen and Moorman (2010) nd evidence
that small rms are more sensitive to shifts in monetary policy, which offers empirical
support for Gertler and Gilchrists claim. We extend this line of research and argue that
favorable monetary environments are most benecial for rms that are most decient in
funding (small rms and nancially constrained rms). Likewise, restrictive monetary
environments have the most negative implications for rms that have the least access to,
and are most reliant on, external sources of funding, which again are rms of relatively
small size and high levels of nancial constraints.
We investigate the relation between monetary conditions and the longterm
reversal in stock prices for both winner and loser stocks. Our evidence supports the
contention that the prominence of the reversal pattern is conditional on the monetary
environment. In particular, a strong reversal pattern exists for losers during periods when
monetary conditions are expansive, while there is no signicant reversal for losers when
monetary conditions are restrictive. We nd that this observation holds even after
excluding January returns from the analysis. Furthermore, we nd the most substantial
price rebound occurs for rms that are small, nancially constrained, and nancially
distressed, that is, rms that have characteristics that suggest they are funding decient.
1
A comparable relation exists with winner stocks, as we nd that when monetary
conditions are restrictive, small, nancially constrained winners suffer the most. This
nding is consistent with the contention that the availability of nancing is more
important for rms that have relatively limited access to funding sources.
Overall, our evidence supports the contention that the monetary environment is
an underlying factor that is at least partially responsible for the reversal pattern in loser and
winner stocks. Furthermore, our results provide an explanation for Fama and Frenchs
(1996) observation that the threefactor model captures the longrun reversal pattern. We
argue that small rms and nancially unstable rms, which according to Fama and French
comprise a large part of the loser portfolio, are more sensitive to monetary conditions. For
such rms, the availability of nancing is a prominent concern so the rms are more
dependent on the monetary environment. Based on this premise, periods evidenced by
greater availability of nancing are especially benecial for these nancially constrained
rms as it provides access to capital to nance rm operations and for investors to
accumulate the stock.
1
The discussion in Fama and French (1996) describes small rms and value rms as being more susceptible to
nancing problems.
4 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT