The Invention of an Investment Incentive for Pharmaceutical Innovation

Published date01 December 2012
Date01 December 2012
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jwip.12001
AuthorShamnad Basheer
The Journal of World Intellectual Property (2012) Vol. 15, no. 5–6, pp. 305–364
doi: 10.1111/jwip.12001
The Invention of an Investment Incentive
for Pharmaceutical Innovation
Shamnad Basheer
West Bengal National University of Juridical Sciences
Pharmaceutical drugs are often hailed as the poster child for the propositionthat patents foster accelerated rates
of innovation.This sentiment stems, in large part, from the belief that pharmaceutical research and development
(R&D) entails significant costs and resources. I argue that if the role of the patent regime is one of fostering
higher amounts of investment in the R&D process,it is better served by a direct investment protection regime,
where the protection does not depend upon whether or not the underlying idea behind the drug is “new” and
“inventive”,two central tenets of patent law.Rather, anydrug that successfully makes it past the regulatory filter
ought to be entitled to protection, since its discovery and development entail significant investment and risk.
Owing to the sub-optimality of the current patent regime in protecting intensive pharmaceutical R&D
investments from free riders, I propose a comprehensive investment protection regime that helps recoup all
investments incurred during the drug discovery and development process. Though similar to existing data
protection regimes in some respects, it differs in others. Firstly, it enables a recovery of all R&D costs, and
not only costs associated with clinical trials. Secondly, unlike patentsand data exclusivity, which offer uniform
periods of protection, it rewards investments in a proportionate manner, wherein drug originators are entitled
to protection against free riders only until such time as they recoup their specific investments and earn a rate of
return on investment dependent inter alia on the health value of the drug.
I consider a pure marketexclusivity based investment protection regime but note thatit is likely to foster exces-
sive pricing and subject the market to the dictates of a single firm. In the alternative, I consider a compensatory
liability model based on a novelcost sharing methodology, where follow-onentrants are free to manufacture the
drug, but must pay a reasonable amount of compensation to the originator.Lastly, I consider a reimbursement
model, where the costs of drug discovery and development arereimbursed through public funding and prizes.
Once it is appreciatedthat the function of investment protection is better addressed through a separateregime,
the pressure on patents to fulfil a role for which it is not intrinsically suited, abates. This point is an important
one to appreciate, as the conflation between patent protection and investment protection has caused many to
argue for a dilution of the patentabilitythreshold.
Keywords innovation; patent; pharmaceutical; TRIPS
Most developed nations resortto two key legal instruments to incentivize pharmaceutical innovation,
namely patents and data exclusivity. In this article, I investigate the optimality of these legal regimes
to foster pharmaceutical innovation.Finding that they suffer serious shortcomings, I propose a novel
investment protection regime.
As far back as 1976, a commentator noted that “[w]ithout patents, the return from investment
in pharmaceutical research and development would fall to zero, and private companies would no
longer engage in research and development” (Schwartzman, 1976).
This sentiment continues unabated till this day, and even those that question the general nexus
between patents and innovation admit that the pharmaceutical industry is an exception (Roin, 2009;
Landes and Posner, 2003, p. 316).1Illustratively, Bessen and Meurer, two of the most vocal critics of
the patent system, note that “(i)n some industries, such as pharmaceuticals, patents provide strong
C2012 Blackwell PublishingLtd 305
Shamnad Basheer The Invention of an Investment Incentive
positive incentives to invest in innovation. But in many other industries, perhaps most, patents fail
to perform like property and they may actually discourage innovation” (Bessen and Meurer, 2008a,
p. 19; Bessen and Meurer, 2008b).
While this statement may hold true at a general level, I take issue with the underlying sentiment
that patents serve as optimal investment inducing instruments. I argue that if the role of the patent
system is conceptualized as one of fostering higher levels of investment into the pharmaceutical
research and development (R&D) process, this function is more optimally achieved through a direct
investment protection regime that does not depend on compliance with traditional patentability
criteria such as “novelty” and “inventive step” (Barton, 2003).2
In other words, a regime that grants comprehensive market exclusivity to new drugs against free
riders until such time as the investment in the discovery and development of that drug is recouped
is preferable to a patent regime. I elaborate upon such a regime in the ensuing parts. This regime
draws in some ways from existing regulatory data exclusivity regimes, which protect investment
costs incurred in the course of generating regulatory data through clinical trials, that is, “safety”
and “efficacy” data, which are required to be submitted to a drug regulatory authority to procure
marketing approval (Mossinghoff, 1999). This regulatory data generation accounts for a major part
of drug discovery and development costs (DiMasi et al., 2003, p. 165). Countries such as the United
States and the European Union countries (hereinafter “EU”) protectthe investments underlying this
data generation by granting a fixed term of marketexclusivity, during which time no competitor can
rely on the data submitted by the drug originator.
However, while a data exclusivity regime could be considered an explicit investment protection
tool and is therefore more optimal than a patent regime on this count, it suffers from certain
shortcomings. Firstly, it provides for a uniform period of protection, sans any consideration of the
specific investment made per drug or the health impact of a drug. Secondly, it only accounts for the
costs incurred during the clinical trial process and excludes significant investments made at the drug
discovery and pre-clinical stages.
I advocate a comprehensive, yet calibrated investment protection regime that grants protection
from free riders who threaten to disrupt the market share of the drug originator with a largely
“similar” drug molecule, until such time as the investments are recouped along with a rate of return
on the investment that broadly tallies with the cost of capital (CoC) and is commensurate with the
health impact of the drug (hereafter referred to as an “appropriate rate of return”).
I first consider a standard market exclusivity model, and note its advantages and disadvantages.
In the alternative, I consider a compensatory liability regime, which eschews any kind of market
exclusivity, leaving the drug originator with the mere right to claim reasonable compensation from
follow-on entrants.3I propose a new frameworkfor assessing fair compensation in this regard. I then
consider a reimbursement model, where the costs of R&D are reimbursed through public funding
and/or prizes.
Once it is appreciated that the function of investment protection is better addressed through
a separate regime, the pressure on patents to fulfil a role for which it is not intrinsically suited,
abates. This point is an important one to appreciate,as the conflation between patent protection and
investment protection has caused many to argue for a dilution of the patentability threshold.4
Contribution
The key contribution of this article is in demonstrating that a comprehensive investment protection
regime is far more optimal than the current patent and data exclusivity regimes in protecting the
significant investments in drug discovery and development.
306
C2012 Blackwell PublishingLtd
The Journal of World IntellectualProperty (2012) Vol. 15, no. 5–6
The Invention of an Investment Incentive Shamnad Basheer
Although scholars have highlighted the limitations of the patent regime in supporting pharma-
ceutical innovationin an optimal manner, none haveproposed a comprehensive investmentprotection
regime, as that proposed in this article. Even those that focus on investment protection advocate the
use of the data exclusivity regime. This article demonstrates the limitations of the data exclusivity
regime,the most obvious of which is that the protection is tied to the submission of regulatorydata and
is meant to cover only those costs incurred during clinical trials. More importantly, data exclusivity
regimes offer uniform periods of protection,which may either under-compensate or over-compensate
the drug originator.
Lastly, the article considers a novel compensatory liability model in order to thwart potential
abuses of the granted monopoly by drug originators who price drugs excessively and/or fail to
supply the market adequately. Under such a model, drug originators do not have exclusive rights
over their drugs; rather, follow-on innovators can enter the market and compete, upon the payment
of reasonable compensation to the drug originator. The article proposes a novel methodology of
computing compensation, whereby a reasonable amount, which balances the interests of both the
drug originator and the follow-onmanufacturer, is to be paid. The compensation methodology takes
into account the global nature of pharmaceutical innovation and the international market for drugs.
Par ts
The article proceeds as follows.
The section entitled “Drug Discovery and Development: An Overview” outlines the framework
for pharmaceutical R&D in order to help appreciate the intensive nature of investments and risks
underlying pharmaceutical innovation.
The section entitled “Patents,Innovation and Investment Protection”explores the role of patents
in pharmaceutical innovation and points out why the regime is sub-optimal from the point of view
of protecting investments.
The section entitled “Data Exclusivity and Pharmaceutical Innovation” discusses the data ex-
clusivity regime (as prevalent in the United States and EU) and its nexus with pharmaceutical
innovation.
The section entitled “Investment Protection Regime” outlines a comprehensive “investment
protection” regime,under which drug originators are granted market exclusivity fora certain number
of years after the drug has been approved. This period of protection is not a uniform one, but is
based on the time taken by drug originators to recover the costs incurred in relation to each drug, as
also an appropriate rateof return on investment based on the “health impact” of the drug, measured
through existing metrics such as quality-adjusted life years (QALYs)and disability-adjusted life years
(DALYs).5Such a calibratedprotection regime is more optimal from a policy perspective, as it avoids
over-compensating or under-compensating drug originators. Most importantly, it helps prevent the
proliferation of “me too” drugs6through a process commonly referred to as evergreening.7
Owing to the potential dangers associated with market exclusivity, I also consider a compulsory
licencing/compensatory liability regime, where the drug originator is not vested with exclusive rights
over the relevant drug market. Rather, any follow-on generic competitor may enter the market upon
the payment of equitable remuneration. I propose a novel compensatory methodology, taking into
account the costs of drug discovery and development and the relative market shares of the originator
and the follow-on generic entrant(s).
Lastly, I consider a reimbursement model as an alternative investment protection instrument,
where the costs of R&D are reimbursed through public funding and/or prizes.
In the section entitled “Patents, Upstream Inventions and Incentives”, I note that despite the
sub-optimality of the patent regime, member states cannot dispense with it, owing to the existence
C2012 Blackwell PublishingLtd
The Journal of World IntellectualProperty (2012) Vol. 15, no. 5–6 307

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT