The Interplay of Relational Governance and Formal Control in Horizontal Alliances: A Social Contract Perspective

AuthorThorsten Schäffler,Carl Marcus Wallenburg
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jscm.12041
Date01 April 2014
Published date01 April 2014
THE INTERPLAY OF RELATIONAL GOVERNANCE AND
FORMAL CONTROL IN HORIZONTAL ALLIANCES: A
SOCIAL CONTRACT PERSPECTIVE
CARL MARCUS WALLENBURG AND THORSTEN SCH
AFFLER
WHUOtto Beisheim School of Management
Governance is critical to an alliance relationship as it aids in curbing
opportunism and thus in achieving higher performance. While research
suggests relational governance as well as formal control mechanisms as
viable means to reduce opportunistic behavior in an alliance relationship,
the effectiveness of the interplay of these governance forms remains an
important issue. This research addresses this challenge by applying social
contract theory to resolve the uncertainties surrounding whether relational
governance, exercised by joint actions in the performance measurement
process (PMP), can be effectively complemented by the formal control
mechanisms of output and process controls. Based on a survey of 197
horizontal alliances of German logistics service providers and using struc-
tural equation modeling, we find that if formal control mechanisms are
legitimized by underlying agreements, which are established through rela-
tional governance (i.e., joint actions), the two governance forms indeed
complement each other. However, if no such legitimization through social
contracts is present, the complementation is counterproductive. Further-
more, it is shown that opportunism in the setting of horizontal alliances
is also detrimental to alliance success.
Keywords: partnering (alliances); performance measurement; social contract theory;
relational governance; structural equation modeling
INTRODUCTION
Over the last two decades, a trend toward more
cooperative ventures has emerged, with many
companies, especially in the logistics sector, active in
one or more horizontal alliances (Cruijssen, Cools &
Dullaert, 2007a; Cruijssen, Dullaert & Fleuren, 2007b;
Das & Rahman, 2010; Schmoltzi & Wallenburg,
2011). The factors behind this trend are multifaceted
and include aspects such as increased competition,
a greater need to provide products and services on a
regional or global basis instead of focusing only on
local customers, and requirements to make larger
investments in supply chain assets (e.g., IT systems).
Given these factors, partnering with other companies
at the same level of the value chain can yield competi-
tive advantage. The motivations for companies to
enter horizontal alliances are diverse, ranging from
the desire to acquire additional competencies and to
increase market penetration to goals related to
improving service quality and productivity (Cruijssen
et al., 2007a,b; Hofenk, Schipper, Semejin &
Gelderman, 2011; Schmoltzi & Wallenburg, 2011).
Yet, despite a long history of horizontal alliances,
many fail to meet expectations and are terminated
(Langfield-Smith, 2008); as many as 40 percent to
70 percent of horizontal alliances fail in some indus-
tries (Kale, Dyer & Singh, 2002; Spekman, Isabella &
MacAvoy, 2000; Taylor, 2005), with opportunistic
actions of alliance members often emphasized as the
main reason for failure (Das, 2004; Das & Rahman,
2010). In general, effective alliance management
through the establishment of appropriate governance
mechanisms has been identified as a measure to
reduce opportunistic behavior among alliance
members, which increases the likelihood of success
(Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hoetker & Mellewigt, 2009;
Lee & Cavusgil, 2006; Schmoltzi & Wallenburg,
2012). The governance mechanisms are “safeguards
Acknowledgments: The authors want to thank Jason Miller from
The Ohio State University for his support in the analysis phase
of this research project and the K
uhne-Foundation for its gener-
ous funding that made this research possible.
April 2014 41
that firms put in place to govern interorganizational
exchange” to “minimize exposure to opportunism”
(Jap & Ganesan, 2000, p. 230).
Compared with vertical alliances, horizontal
alliances are especially prone to opportunistic behav-
ior due to different idiosyncrasies. First, interdepen-
dence is lower (Rindfleisch, 2000), because horizontal
alliances are not based on a clear buyersupplier rela-
tionship.
1
Instead of one party being a customer to
others, the alliance members are at the same level of
the value chain. An example for the logistics industry
are logistics service providers (LSPs) operating a joint
transportation network. A second idiosyncrasy is
co-opetitionthe simultaneous existence of coopera-
tion and competition among the parties (Das & Teng,
2000b; Wilhelm, 2011; Zeng & Chen, 2003). Addition-
ally, horizontal alliances often are multilateral and
entail three or more firms (Schmoltzi & Wallenburg,
2011).
In horizontal alliances, relational governance has
been shown in prior literature (e.g., Schmoltzi &
Wallenburg, 2012; Steinicke, Wallenburg & Schmoltzi,
2012; Wallenburg & Raue, 2011) to be an especially
important form of governance. It enforces obligations,
promises, and expectations through social processes
that promote relational norms and rely on mutual
adjustment and joint action (Heide & John, 1992;
Poppo & Zenger, 2002). Here, joint action in key
areas of the alliance (Joshi & Stump, 1999) is of vital
importance. One such key area is performance mea-
surement (PM; Bititci et al., 1997). Hence, this
research proposes that joint action in the correspond-
ing performance measurement processes (PMP) is a
means to establish specific social processes and rela-
tional norms, which function as safeguards against
opportunism. Transaction cost economics theory
(TCE) points out that formal control mechanisms also
can mitigate exchange hazards and reduce the risk of
opportunistic behavior (Heide, Wathne & Rokkan,
2007; Poppo & Zenger, 2002; Anderson and Weitz
1992; Williamson, 1985).
This raises the question of whether it is effective to
complement relational governance in horizontal alli-
ances with formal governance mechanisms to
maximize the effect. At first sight such an approach
may appear very promising, because process control
and output control as key elements of formal control
(Jaworski, Stathakopoulos & Krishnan, 1993) could
build on the joint PMP in their monitoring and
evaluation of processes and outputs. However, prior
research does not show consensus in this respect.
While one stream of research clearly outlines the bene-
fits of combining relational governance with formal
control (Cannon, Achrol & Gundlach, 2000; Poppo &
Zenger, 2002), a second stream notes their substitu-
tive or even antagonistic nature in that formal control
may undermine social processes, hamper the forma-
tion of trust, or even breed a situation of mistrust that
instead increases opportunism (Dyer & Singh, 1998;
Gulati, 1995).
The importance of the fundamental question of
whether it is effective or, instead, counterproductive
to complement relational governance with formal
control has been highlighted in a call for research
by Rindfleisch et al. (2010), who postulate that
further investigations with respect to governance in
alliances should be undertaken and that this research
should particularly focus on the application of more
than one form of governance. This call was later
reinforced by Gelderman and Vermeulen (2012),
and yet, few researchers have taken steps toward
responding.
This article addresses this research gap and outlines
how the nature of the interplay between different
forms governance is affected by answering the ques-
tion of whether formal control is legitimized, namely
by the social contracts inherent to the alliance, or not.
The idea of social contracts have a long history and
can be traced back to social and political upheavals in
Europe more than 300 years ago (Dunfee, Smith &
Ross, 1999). On the micro level viewed in this
research (i.e., the interfirm level in contrast to the
societal level viewed in early works) social contracts
relate to the explicit or implicit agreement on what
each party is entitled to. While social contracts are not
legally binding and only refer to the common under-
standing, they on the one hand outline what rights
and obligations exist and on the other hand give pro-
tection against illegitimate action. Specifically, this
article builds on social contract theory (Dunfee et al.,
1999) and the work of Heide et al. (2007) in outlin-
ing that legitimization for or against formal control
will be embedded in the relational setup and the spe-
cific forms of joint action.
This focal aspect of the researchthe interaction
between relational governance and formal controlis
complemented with two further contributions: Build-
ing on TCE, this research is the first to outline and
test the specific effects that joint action in the PMP
has in reducing opportunism in horizontal alliances
and, further, the positive effect that reducing oppor-
tunism has on alliance performance. To test the corre-
sponding hypotheses, an empirical methodology is
applied using data from 197 horizontal alliances of
German LSPs. With that, the goal is to enhance the
theoretical understanding regarding the functioning of
different governance forms and the effectiveness
of their interplay for reducing opportunism and
increasing alliance performance.
1
Consequently, subcontracting relationships are not viewed as
horizontal relationships.
Volume 50, Number 2
Journal of Supply Chain Management
42

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT