The Inefficiency of Quasi–Per Se Rules: Regulating Information Exchange in EU and U.S. Antitrust Law

Date01 March 2020
AuthorJerrold Soh,Kenneth Khoo
Published date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ablj.12155
American Business Law Journal
Volume 57, Issue 1, 45–111, Spring 2020
The Inefficiency of Quasi–Per Se
Rules: Regulating Information
Exchange in EU and
U.S. Antitrust Law
Kenneth Khoo*and Jerrold Soh**
It is well understood that the exchange of information between horizontal competi-
tors can violate competition law provisions in both the European Union (EU) and
the United States, namely, article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the
European Union and section 1 of the Sherman Act. However, despite ostensible
similarities between EU and U.S. antitrust law concerning interfirm information
exchange, substantial differences remain. In this article, we make a normative
argument for the U.S. antitrust regime’s approach, on the basis that the United
States’ approach to information exchange is likely to be more efficient than the rele-
vant approach under the EU competition regime. Using economic theories of harm
concerning information exchange to understand the imposition of liability in rela-
tion to “stand-alone” instances of information exchange, we argue that such liabil-
ity must be grounded on the conception of a prophylactic rule. We characterize this
rule as a form of ex ante regulation and explain why it has no ex post counterpart
in antitrust law. In contrast to the U.S. antitrust regime, we argue that the imple-
mentation of such a rule pursuant to EU competition law leads to higher error
costs without a significant reduction in regulatory costs. As a majority of jurisdic-
tions have competition law regimes that resemble EU competition law more closely
than U.S. antitrust law, our thesis has important implications for competition
regimes around the world.
*Sheridan Fellow, National University of Singapore. kennethkhoo@nus.edu.sg.
**Lecturer, Singapore Management University. jerroldsoh@smu.edu.sg. We would like to
thank George Priest, Ian Ayres, Fiona Scott Morton, Ramsi Woodcock, Damian Chalmers,
Andrew Halpin, Tan Cheng Han, Ho Hock Lai, Doni Bloomfield, and the anonymous
reviewers for helpful comments, Teo Jim Yang, Abigail Wong, and Shirley Yong for superb
research support, as well as the ABLJ team (Gideon Mark, Matt Meacham, and Susan Park)
for excellent editorial assistance.
©2020 The Authors
American Business Law Journal ©2020 Academy of Legal Studies in Business
45
INTRODUCTION
Rapid technological innovation over the past few decades has led to an
exponential increase in the ability of firms to store, transmit, and process
information. Hilbert and Lopez estimate that from 1986 to 2007 the
world’s capacity for bidirectional telecommunication has grown by almost
twenty-eight percent per year.
1
In contemporary commerce, firms often
rely on live, readily accessible data and information from other firms in
making important business decisions.
2
For antitrust specialists, the exchange and use of information between
horizontal competitors demands additional scrutiny,
3
as it is closely
related to the competitive structure of the market in which these firms
compete.
4
The relationship is an involved one—information exchange
has ostensibly conflicting effects on the level of competition in a given
market.
5
For example, while the existence of competitive markets is
1
Martin Hilbert & Priscila Lo
´pez, The World’s Technological Capacity to Store, Communicate, and
Compute Information, 332 SCI. 60, 63 (2011) (illustrating in a table how the compound annual
growth rate of telecommunications has grown by twenty-eight percent a year).
2
For example, institutional investors often rely on readily available information from finan-
cial data providers to determine their portfolio compositions. See Eugene F. Fama et al., The
Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information,10I
NTLECON.REV. 1, 20 (1969) (noting empiri-
cal evidence that investors act on the information implications of a stock split almost imme-
diately after the announcement date, supporting the conclusion that stock prices adjust
very rapidly to new information).
3
In this article, we will use the terms “competition law” and “antitrust” as equivalent syno-
nyms for each other. However, when referring to the European Union, we will preference
the “competition law” term over “antitrust;” the reverse will hold true for the U.S. regime.
See ALISON JONES & B.E. SUFRIN,EUCOMPETITION LAW:TEXT,CASES AND MATERIALS 3 (6th
ed. 2016) (noting that in general parlance, competition law is often called by its American
name, “antitrust law”). Our article also focuses on “stand-alone” instances of information
exchange. As will be explained, such initiatives should be distinguished from instances
where the trier of fact uses information exchange (that may or may not come in the form of
interfirm communications) as an evidentiary tool to infer an agreement or concerted prac-
tice under either U.S. antitrust or EU competition law. We do not deny the validity of the
latter. See infra Part II.E.1.
4
See MASSIMO MOTTA,COMPETITION POLICY:THEORY AND PRACTICE 150 (2004) (emphasizing
the role of information exchange in improving the observability of prices and quantities,
and the sustainability of collusion).
5
In this article, we use the term “information exchange” as an equivalent synonym for
“information sharing.” Both terms refer to bilateral or multilateral conduct, as opposed to
facilitating practices that may comprise instances of unilateral behavior (such as unilateral
46 Vol. 57 / American Business Law Journal
consistent with the free exchange of information between firms and con-
sumers, it is also uncontroversial that the exchange of price-sensitive
information may facilitate collusion between competing firms.
6
This com-
plex relationship mirrors the approach that both the EU and
U.S. antitrust regimes have adopted. While many forms of information
exchange between competitors are procompetitive and unlikely to
infringe antitrust law, other types of information exchange will raise
competition concerns and may amount to violation of the law.
7
However,
despite ostensible similarities between EU and U.S. antitrust law con-
cerning interfirm information exchange, the two regimes diverge sub-
stantially regarding the liability imposed upon firms for information
exchanges. Firms face a far greater risk of liability for such exchanges
under the EU competition regime as compared to its U.S. counterpart.
Under the EU competition regime, many forms of information exchange
are subject to a presumption of illegality, which may be difficult for the
firm laboring under the presumption to rebut.
8
In contrast, under the
U.S. antitrust regime, most forms of information exchange are subject to
a “rule of reason” analysis that places the burden of establishing anticom-
petitive effects on the party alleging illegality.
9
This divergence should not come as a surprise. For many years, anti-
trust scholars have noted that relative to the United States, EU
invitations to collude). See ANDREW I. GAVIL ET AL., ANTITRUST LAW IN PERSPECTIVE:CASES,CON-
CEPTS,AND PROBLEMS IN COMPETITION POLICY 396–97 (2002) (noting the distinction between
unilateral practices that might facilitate coordination as opposed to practices that are
adopted by agreement). A “facilitating practice” is “an activity that makes it easier for parties
to coordinate price or other behavior in an anticompetitive way.” See PHILLIPAREEDA &HER-
BERT HOVENKAMP,ANTITRUST LAW 1407B(2d ed. 2003). A facilitating practice makes tacit col-
lusion more likely to occur, and makes tacit collusion more effective. See id. Judge Posner
first coined the term in Richard A. Posner, Information and Antitrust: Reflections on the
Gypsum and Engineers Decisions,67G
EO. L.J. 1187, 1196–97 (1978). It has subsequently
enjoyed extensive use by U.S. antitrust scholars, lawyers, and judges.
6
See generally Matthew Bennett & Philip Collins, The Law and Economics of Information Shar-
ing: The Good, the Bad and the Ugly,6E
UR.COMPETITION J. 311, 315, 320 (2010) (“Well-
informed and confident consumers can play a key role in promoting vigorous competition
between firms…. The primary way in which information sharing can harm consumers is if
it has the effect of facilitating coordination. Specifically, it can play a role in allowing firms
to engage in, and sustain, tacit or explicit coordinated behaviour.”).
7
This is discussed in more detail in infra Part I.
8
See infra Part I.A.2.
9
See infra Part I.A.1.
2020 / Inefficiency of Quasi–Per Se Rules 47

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT