The Increasing Effectiveness of National Gender Quotas, 1990–2010

Published date01 August 2015
AuthorPamela Paxton,Melanie M. Hughes
Date01 August 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12079
PAMELA PAXTON
University of Texas-Austin
MELANIE M. HUGHES
University of Pittsburgh
The Increasing Effectiveness
of National Gender Quotas,
1990–2010
National gender quotas—policies that require a certain percentage of women
candidates or legislators—are becoming more effective over time. Using data on 145
countries from 1990 to 2010, we document this trend with latent growth-curve models.
Part of the explanation for increasing effectiveness is that countries have ratcheted up
targets for women’s inclusion and that quotas are increasingly written in ways that make
them more effective at achieving stated goals. Activists, political elites, and policy mak-
ers have learned over time which quota policies are most effective, resulting in quotas
with provisions that more often lead to success. But, changes in rules alone do not
account for the increasing effectiveness of quotas over time. It appears that changing
norms about women’s incorporation in politics are also increasing quota effectiveness
regardless of policy design.
Gender quotas are arguably one of the most important political
developments of the last 30 years. By 1990 only a handful of countries
used any type of national political quota for women. During the 1990s,
however, Argentina passed a law designed to aggressively advance
women’s representation, and national quotas in various forms began to
proliferate widely. By 2010, more than 60 states had written gender
quotas into their electoral laws or constitutions, mandating that a certain
percentage of women must be included as candidates or legislators
(IDEA 2013; Krook 2009). The spread of quotas has not ended. Today,
countries continue to debate both the adoption of new gender quotas and
reforms to existing quota provisions.
Quotas are designed to “jumpstart” women’s political representa-
tion—to move from incremental gains to substantial growth in women’s
political presence (Dahlerup and Friedenvall 2005; Krook 2009).
Research increasingly demonstrates that quotas are accomplishing this
goal, at least in recent years (Bauer 2008; Beaman et al. 2009; Dahlerup
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 40, 3, August 2015 331
DOI: 10.1111 /lsq.12079
V
C2015 The Comparative Legislative Research Center of The University of Iowa
2006; Hughes 2011; Krook 2009; Tripp and Kang 2008). However,
existing cross-national research on the effect of quotas on women’s
representation is overwhelmingly cross-sectional, analyzes only quotas
adopted before 2000, and/or ignores key policy differences across types
of quotas. Consequently, at least two important questions have been left
unanswered: (1) Have national gender quotas become more effective in
producing gains for women over time? (2) Do differences in quota
design alone explain changes in policy effectiveness? We judge the
effectiveness of a quota based on the success of its implementation or its
ability to meet legislated goals (Jones 2009; Schmidt and Saunders
2004; Schwindt-Bayer 2009). That is, if a country adopts a gender quota
with a 30% threshold or target, the quota is judged as more or less effec-
tive depending on how close the country subsequently comes to electing
30% women to its national legislature.
Existing studies show that policy design can inf‌luence the size of a
gender quota’s effect on women’s legislative representation (e.g., Krook
2009; Matland 2006; Schwindt-Bayer 2009). Quotas with a higher
threshold—those that require a greater share of female candidates or
seats—produce higher levels of women’s legislative presence (Paxton,
Hughes, and Painter 2010; Schwindt-Bayer 2009). Reserved seats,
which set aside a specif‌ic share of seats for women, may be more effec-
tive at increasing women’s numbers than candidate quotas, which affect
only the candidate pool. Within candidate quotas, rules requiring that
women occupy certain positions on candidate lists, called placement
mandates, and measures that penalize parties for failing to comply with
quota provisions, called sanctions for noncompliance, have both been
shown to enhance quota effectiveness (e.g., Schwindt-Bayer 2009).
But, we are not interested here in the average effects of quotas.
Instead, we hope to understand the extent to which quotas and their
effects on women’s representation are changing over time. The quota-
adoption literature emphasizes the importanc e of information sharing
and learning, whereby activists and policy makers look to the experien-
ces and outcomes of other countries when advocating for and making
policy choices (e.g., Krook 2004, 2009). Sharing implies that if quotas
with stronger provisions (e.g., placement mandates) come to be seen as
more effective at reaching stated goals, those pressing for increased polit-
ical representation for women—be they activists, policy makers, or other
elites—should increasingly favor quotas with such provisions, potentially
increasing quota effectiveness over time.
But quota effectiveness could also increase be cause domestic and
international norms about women’s participation in politics have
changed (Berkovitch 1999; Bush 2011; Hughes 2009; Towns 2010).
332 Pamela Paxton and Melanie M. Hughes
Women’s inclusion in politics was historically perceived as problematic
but is now seen as not only acceptable, but desirable (Paxton, Hughes,
and Green 2006). Increasing norms of equality could result in declines
in political party efforts to circumve nt quota targets and a simultaneous
increase in the public’s taste for the inclusion of women, which together
would decrease the need for strong quota provisions to achieve gains
for women.
In this article, we consider the effectiveness of gender quotas in
producing women’s legislative representation over time. Fundamental to
our approach is the idea that countries exhibit trajectories of growth in
women’s representation over time and that quotas should push countries
off their existing trajectory. We examine the effect of quotas in 145
countries from 1990 to 2010, using Latent Growth Curve models
(Bollen and Curran 2006) and controlling for the electoral system,
democratization, and economic development. If quotas are becoming
more effective over time, not only should we see increasingly large
jumps above the existing trajectory of the country, but the percent
women “returned” for a percent increase in the quota threshold should
also increase. We assess whether stronger quota rules—specif‌ically,
placement mandates and sanctions for noncompliance—can fully
account for increasing returns for quotas over time or whether better
returns are seen even in countries with weaker quota provisions.
The Influence of Gender Quotas
Gender quotas are laws or party rules requiring that women make
up a certain percentage of a candidate list, parliamentary assembly, com-
mittee, or government. We focus here on national gender quotas—those
that affect national legislatures and are system-wide. Broadly, quotas are
either reserved seats, which set aside a certain share of seats in the
national legislature for women, or legislated candidate quotas, which
require that all political parties in a system f‌ield a certain percentage of
female candidates or nominees.
Numerous case studies have evaluated the inf‌luence of gender quo-
tas on women’s numerical presence in national legislatures, f‌inding that
quotas sometimes increase women’s numbers (e.g., Dahlerup 2006;
Jones 2004; Krook 2009).
1
These studies do not consider how growth in
women’s representation in countries with quotas compares to change in
countries without quotas (except see Archenti and Johnson 2006). Most
countries are on upward trajectories of women’s political representation.
If women’s representation is growing at similar rates in countries without
333Increasing Effectiveness of Gender Quotas

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT