The Income Elasticity of Nonlife Insurance: A Reassessment

Date01 June 2016
AuthorGiovanni Millo
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12051
Published date01 June 2016
THE INCOME ELASTICITY OF NONLIFE INSURANCE:
AR
EASSESSMENT
Giovanni Millo
ABSTRACT
In aggregate insurance regressions at the country level, the question whether
insurance is a normal or superior good translates into whether income
elasticity is significantly greater than one or not. Twenty-five years after a
seminal article, I reassess the income elasticity of nonlife insurance by means
of homogeneous and heterogeneous versions of the common correlated
effects estimator, controlling for common factors and individual trends and
characterizing the average behavior of insurance markets while allowing
for individual heterogeneity. The evidence supports the existence of a
cointegrating behavior between insurance consumption and GDP and the
view of nonlife insurance as a normal good.
INTRODUCTION
In aggregate insurance regressions at the country level, GDP shows up as by far the
most important driver of growth, proving positive, and significant, for example, in all
studies considered in Outreville’s (2013a) review. Hence, characterizing the long-run
elasiticity of aggregate premiums to GDP is of great value to practitioners trying to
forecast development trends in the medium to longer term. On the other hand, the
theoretical debate has long been going on whether insurance is a normal or a superior
good, translating in an aggregate setting into whether said elasticity is significantly
greater than one or not. I address the question of whether insurance is a normal or a
superior good from an aggregate perspective; that is, do market premiums grow less
or more than proportionally with economic development?
Giovanni Millo is at the Generali Research & Development at Generali S.p.A., via Machiavelli 3,
34132 Trieste, Italy. Millo can be contacted via e-mail: giovanni.millo@generali.com. The article
has benefited greatly from discussions with Gaetano Carmeci; nevertheless, all the errors are
the author’s responsibility. The views expressed are solely his own and do not necessarily
reflect those of his employer. The author is grateful to Swiss Re Research and Consulting for
providing missing data from back issues of sigma. All the computations in the article are done
inside the R open-source environment for statistical computing (R Development Core
Team, 2012), generally using the plm add-on package for panel data econometrics (Croissant
and Millo, 2008). This article has been prepared as a dynamic document with the Sweave utility
(Leisch, 2002) according to the principles of literate statistical practice.
© 2014 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol. 83, No. 2, 335–361 (2016).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12051
335
In two seminal articles, Beenstock, Dickinson, and Khajuria (1986, 1988) were the
first to consider the behavior of, respectively, life and nonlife
1
insurance with
respect to economic growth by pooling a number of time series from different
countries. Twenty-five years from Beenstock, Dickinson, and Khajuria’s influential
twin articles, methodology has progressed to the point of successfully tackling a
number of then-unresolved problems, already acknowledged by the original
authors: in particular, cross-sectional between-country heterogeneity in the
coefficients of interest (Beenstock, Dickinson, and Khajuria, 1988, p. 259) and
serial correlation (Beenstock, Dickinson, and Khajuria, 1988, p. 267).
2
New
methodological concerns have emerged since, to which the scientific community
paid scant attention or of which it was even scarcely aware back then: most
notably, cross-sectional and spatial correlation, and nonstationarity of variables in
panel data. The latter is possibly leading to spurious regressions in the sense
of Granger and Newbold (1974), so that results of regressions between nonstation-
ary data must be taken with care, at least unless cointegration is proved (see
Phillips and Moon, 1999). The former, cross-sectional correlation, can assume
different forms, essentially based on whether its scope is local and distance
decaying (spatial correlation) or globally affecting every country in the cross-
section (as in common factor models), as formalized in Pesaran and Tosetti (2011),
this second case being the most problematic, as symptomatic of a specification
flaw possibly leading to inconsistent estimates if the common factors’ influence
is not accounted for. National insurance markets are notoriously affected by
common, international factors, like shifts in the global price of reinsurance,
single catastrophal losses of more-than-national scope or global changes in
risk conditions, as most notably happened in 2001 after the World Trade
Center attack, and therefore controlling for this kind of dependence is of the
utmost importance. Fortunately, new estimators are available that are able to
effectively account for unobserved common factors, as will be detailed in the
following.
From the point of view of information, time has again healed some problematic
aspects acknowledged in the original study, like the short time span available
(Beenstock, Dickinson, and Khajuria, 1988, p. 260). Today we draw on a new Sigma
data set, beginning from the year 1970 as in Beenstock, Dickinson, and Khajuria (1988)
but now extending until 2010, thus spanning 40 years of insurance history (Sigma,
various issues). In turn, the geographical scope of the database has been constantly
extended, so that now with respect to the 1981 version in Beenstock, Dickinson, and
Khajuria it comprises a much larger number of countries and completely new areas
like Eastern Europe. Although many “new” countries have been added only recently,
on average the Sigma data set has become “long” enough to allow employing modern
panel time series methods.
1
Beenstock, Dickinson, and Khajuria (1986, 1988) use the term propertyliability as in standard
insurance parlance, meaning total nonlife premiums and hence including other lines,
notably—but not only—accident, health, and transport.
2
The use of the Durbin–Watson statistic in a dynamic model is problematic (see Dezhbakhsh,
1990).
336 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT