The impact of the managed care backlash on health care spending

Published date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12306
Date01 March 2020
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.51, No. 1, Spring 2020
pp. 59–108
The impact of the managed care backlash
on health care spending
Maxim L. Pinkovskiy
The health spending slowdown associated with the managedcare revolution in the 1990s suggests
that managed care may have been successful in controlling health care spending. I exploit the
passage of state regulation during the “managedcare backlash” as well as geographic variation
in managed care intensity to measure the impact of managed care on spending. I find that
restricting managed care causes a large and significant increase in hospital spending, which
cannot be explained by changes in hospital market concentration, other regulatory activity, and
multiple other possible explanations. I also do not find effects of the backlash on mortality.
1. Introduction
The growth of health care spending as a share of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) has been
one of the defining features of the US health care sector. Health care spending nearly doubled as
a share of GDP in 30 years, rising from 8.3% in 1977 to 15.9% in 2007, and often has grown
at a linear (and hence, unsustainable) rate for decades at a time. The problem of controlling
the growth in health care spending and ensuring its efficient use is particularly urgent because
health spending forms a significant part of US government expenditures, putting pressure on
other government priorities and tax rates, and making coverage expansion expensive.
The overalltrend of rising health care expenditures in the United States saw a temporary break
during the 1990s, when health care spending as a share of GDP held steady at 13.3% from 1993
to 2000. This stabilization of health care expenditures coincided with the peak of the so-called
Federal Reserve Bank of New York; maxim.pinkovskiy@ny.frb.org.
This paper was written as the first chapter of the author’s Ph.D. dissertation at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
I am immensely grateful to Daron Acemoglu, Amy Finkelstein, and Jerry Hausman for guidance and advice. I am very
grateful to David Autor, Manasi Deshpande, Nicole Gorton, TalGross, Jonathan Gruber, Andrew Haughwout, Katherine
Ho, Horacio Larreguy, Claire Lim, WilliamNober, Matthew Notowidigdo, Benjamin Olken, Christopher Palmer, James
Poterba,Adam Sacar ny,Joe Shapiro, James Snyder, Heidi Williams,seminar par ticipants at MIT,the American Enterprise
Institute, the Bureau of Economic Analysis, Mathematica, and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and conference
participants at the 2014 System Applied Microeconomics Conference (Minneapolis, MN), 2017 Society for Econometric
Measurement Conference (Cambridge, MA), and 2018 National TaxAssociation Annual Conference (New Orleans, LA)
for extremely valuable feedback, comments, and suggestions. I am very grateful to Jean Roth, Mohan Ramanujan and
the NBER for helping me with access to data from the AHA Annual Survey. I am very grateful to Chad Syverson and
two anonymous referees for very thoughtful comments. I am deeply indebted to Laurence Baker for sharing with me his
county-level HMO penetration measure and to Susan Laudicina for sending me her publication,“State Legislative Health
Care and Insurance Issues.” Finally,I am very grateful to the Paul and Daisy Soros Fellowship for intellectual stimulation,
and to the National Science Foundation Graduate Research FellowshipProgram (NSF GRFP) and to the Humane Studies
Fellowship (Institute for Humane Studies) for graduate study funding.
C2020, The RAND Corporation. 59
60 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
FIGURE 1
US NATIONAL HEALTH EXPENDITURES, % OF GDP [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
8
10
12
14
16
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Year
US National Health Expenditures, % of GDP
Source: Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS): National Health Expenditure Accounts.
managed care revolution, which saw the replacement of conventional insurers (who reimbursed
hospitals and physicians for services provided without regulating utilization) by health insurance
organizations that managed the medical care of their enrollees. The organizational innovation of
managed care firms was to integrate physicians and insurers partially or completely to align their
incentives and discourage physicians from inducing demand for medical care. The most well-
known type of managed care organization,the health maintenance organization (HMO), restricted
its patients to see a strictly delimited network of providers, who sometimes were its employees.
Although the growth of health insurance premiums slowed significantly, patients and physi-
cians chafed at managed care controls. At the end of the 1990s, there arose a widespread backlash
against managed care cost containment practices, with increasingly negative media coverage of
managed care. Ultimately, state governments passed “patients’ bills of rights” that limited the
ability of managed care firms to restrict care and shape the incentives of medical practitioners.
Health care spending resumed rising as a share of GDP in 2001, at the height of the managed care
backlash. Figure 1 presents the time series of the US health care share between 1977 and 2007,
with both the slowdown during the managed care revolutionand the speedup during the backlash
clearly visible. It remains an open question whether managed care succeeded in stabilizing US
health care spending or whether the slowdown in US health care spending growth in the 1990s
was a product of other factors (Glied, 2003).
This article finds that the managed care backlash, as captured by regulations passed to
restrict managed care cost containment practices (hereafter, backlash regulations), in fact caused
the subsequent increases in hospital spending. I show that passage of backlash regulations was
associated with increases in hospital spending shares in counties with high managed care intensity,
proxied bythe estimates of county HMO penetration from Baker and Phibbs (2002). Using county-
level data over time, I employ a research design that is robust to key potential confounders,
including the endogeneity of passage of the backlash regulations and trends in health spending
that depend on managed care intensity but are unrelated to the passage of the backlash regulations.
The key dependent variable of myanalysis is the hospital spending share of county personal
income, which I define as the hospital share. My results indicate that the managed care backlash
increased the growth rate of the hospital share by 1.4 percentage points per backlash regulation
in a county with maximum possible managed care intensity relative to a county with minimum
intensity.The magnitude of this estimate is consistent with the managed care backlash accounting
for over 90% of the overall increase in the nationwide growth rate of the hospital share observed
C
The RAND Corporation 2020.
PINKOVSKIY /61
FIGURE 2
EFFECTS OF MAJOR PASSAGEOF BACKLASH REGULATIONS ON HEALTHSHARE OF COUNTY
PERSONAL INCOME [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
-.05
-.04
-.03
-.02
-.01
0
.01
.02
.03
.04
.05
Percentage point increase in health share
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
Years after major passage
Counties in top quartile by 1995 HMO penetration
Counties in bottom quartile by 1995 HMO penetration
Year of major passage is year in which the county's state passed the largest number of backlash regulations.
Effects of Major Passage of Backlash Regulations
Source: Author’scalculations. Blue and red lines show percentage point increases in AHA hospital spending as a share
of county personal income for counties in the top and bottom quartiles of HMO penetration in 1995.
between the 1995–2000 period and the 2001–2005 period. My findings are robust to alternative
spending measures. The rise in hospital spending growth appears to work through an increase
in spending per hospital employee, rather than through an increase in the number of hospital
employees, and likely, through an increase in hospital admissions rather than through an increase
in expenditures per admission. I detect no effect of backlash regulations on mortality, although
I cannot rule out mortality impacts large enough that, at typical values of a statistical life, the
willingness to pay for them would exceed the increase in health spending associated with the
managed care backlash. I provide a variety of robustness checks for my results by conducting
permutation tests on the data, showing that the passage of the backlash regulations predates the
resumption of health care spending growth, exploring the possibility that either HMO penetration
or the backlash regulations variable may be proxyingfor other measures of county heterogeneity
(such as urbanization or population density) or relevant developments in the health care sector
(such as hospital consolidation and other regulatory movements unrelated to managed care),
and varying the construction of my regulation measures. Viewing the managed care backlash
regulations as plausibly exogenous variation in dampening the intensity of managed care, my
results are consistent with the thesis that managed care reduced spending without measurably
sacrificing outcomes.
I illustrate my main result in Figure 2. I define the year of major passage for a county as
the year in which its state passed its largest number of backlash regulations, a proxy for the peak
of the political backlash in the state. I then plot the average growth rates of the hospital share
for high and low HMO penetration counties relative to the year of major passage. It is clear
that the growth of the hospital share is low (in fact, substantially negative) before the year of
major passage in the high penetration counties, whereas the growth rate of the hospital share is
higher (generally positive) before the year of major passage in the lowpenetration counties. Both
growth rates are evolving fairly continuously up to the year of major passage, with perhaps a
slight upward trend in the growth rate for the high penetration counties. However, two years after
the year of major passage, the growth of the hospital share shoots up to nearly 5% for the high
penentration counties, much higher than the growth rate for low penetration counties. The growth
rate for the high penetration counties then declines somewhat, but still remains positiveand much
C
The RAND Corporation 2020.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT