The Impact of Ambiguity on Managerial Investment and Cash Holdings

Date01 September 2014
AuthorMonica Neamtiu,Christopher D. Williams,Hal D. White,Nemit Shroff
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12079
Published date01 September 2014
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 41(7) & (8), 1071–1099, September/October 2014, 0306-686X
doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12079
The Impact of Ambiguity on Managerial
Investment and Cash Holdings
MONICA NEAMTIU,NEMIT SHROFF,HAL D. WHITE
AND CHRISTOPHER D. WILLIAMS
Abstract: Standard finance theory suggests that managers invest in projects that, in expecta-
tion, produce returns that justify the use of capital. An underlying assumption is that managers
have the information necessary to understand the distributional properties of the pay-offs
underlying the decision. This paper examines firm investment behavior when managers are
likely to find it more challenging to develop expectations of pay-offs, namely during periods of
increased macroeconomic ambiguity. In particular, we examine how macroeconomic ambiguity
– proxied by the variance premium (Drechsler, 2010) and the dispersion in forecasts of
corporate profits from the Survey of Professional Forecasters (Anderson et al., 2009) – impacts
managerial capital investment and cash holdings. Consistent with ambiguity theory, we find
that macroeconomic ambiguity is negatively associated with capital investment and positively
associated with cash holdings. These results are robust to alternative explanations related to risk,
investor sentiment and economic conditions. Moreover, consistent with recent theoretical real
options literature, we find that ambiguity reduces the value of investment opportunities, while
risk increases the value of such opportunities. Overall, these findings provide initial empirical
evidence on the economic distinction between ambiguity and risk with respect to managerial
investment and cash holdings.
Keywords: ambiguity, risk, investment, cash holdings
1. INTRODUCTION
Within a firm, the allocation of capital to its highest value use is one of the most
important roles of a manager. The central determinant of successful capital allocation
is the precision with which a manager is able to identify cash flow prospects and
apply appropriate discount rates for the respective investment decisions. Typically,
the investment literature assumes that managers know, or behave as if they know,
The first author is an Associate Professor of Accounting at the University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ. The
second author is an Assistant Professor of Accounting at Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Boston,
MA. The third and fourth authors are Assistant Professors of Accounting at the University of Michigan,
Ann Arbor, MI. The authors would like to thank Andrew Stark (Editor), an anonymous referee, Ilia Dichev,
Raffi Indjejikian, Feng Li, Russell Lundholm, Greg Miller, Mike Minnis, Marlene Plumlee and workshop
participants at the 2010 University of Michigan Harvey Kapnick Conference and the Seoul National
University for useful comments and suggestions.
Address for correspondence: Christopher D. Williams, Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, 701
Tappan Street, Ann Arbor, MI 48109, USA.
e-mail: williacd@umich.edu
C
2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 1071
1072 NEAMTIU, SHROFF, WHITE AND WILLIAMS
the probability distributions of the cash flows and discount rates related to potential
projects. In other words, although project pay-offs are ex-ante unknown, managers feel
confident in their assessment of investment pay-off probabilities.
Recent theoretical work by Nishimura and Ozaki (2007), however, argues that
managers facing a decision regarding irreversible investment may not always have
complete confidence in their perceived pay-off probability measures. As Nishimura
and Ozaki (2007) state, managers “might think other probability measures perturbed
from the original one are also possible.” This uncertainty regarding investment pay-
off – characterized by a set of probability measures rather than a single probability
measure – is defined as ambiguity, or Knightian uncertainty.1The intuition developed
in Nishimura and Ozaki (2007) draws from the large theoretical and experimental
literature on ambiguity (e.g., Ellsberg, 1961; Gilboa and Schmeidler, 1989; Bewley,
2002), which builds on Knight (1921).2
The purpose of this paper is to examine the impact of ambiguity on managerial
investment and cash holding decisions. The ambiguity literature suggests that, in the
presence of ambiguity, ambiguity-averse individuals behave as if they assume “worst-
case’ outcome scenarios – i.e., they incorporate the worst possible pay-off probability
measure in their consideration set into their decision. With respect to managerial
investment, ambiguity-averse managers place a lower reservation price on potential
projects than would be predicted using a rational expectations framework (Nishimura
and Ozaki, 2007). As a result, their investment level declines, as anticipated project
pay-offs do not meet the lower reservation prices and they shift to holding riskless
assets instead (Dow and Werlang, 1992; Epstein and Schneider, 2010). Following this
intuition, we predict that when managers find it more difficult to develop expectations
of future investment pay-offs (i.e., when they are faced with ambiguity), they are likely
to reduce their capital expenditures and increase their cash holdings.3
To capture the impact of ambiguity, we develop our models of investment and cash
holdings based on prior literature. In particular, we model a firm’sinvestment decision
using Euler equations (e.g., Whited, 1992; Hubbard et al., 1995; Love, 2003), and we
model a firm’s cash holdings following Opler et al. (1999).4Our proxies for ambiguity
are the variance premium (Drechsler, 2010) and dispersion in forecasts of corporate
profits by the Survey of Professional Forecasters (Anderson et al., 2009).
1 The term “Knightian uncertainty” is based on the seminal work of Knight (1921), which points out that
ambiguity is a fundamentally different concept than risk. Specifically, risk relates to known, or objective,
uncertainty, as in the roll of a die, where the outcome probabilities are known, or the probabilities can
be estimated with confidence. In contrast, ambiguity relates to subjective uncertainty, where outcome
probabilities are unknown, and the decisionmaker fears the estimated model is incorrect. Note that,
although both risk and ambiguity ultimately relate to uncertainty regarding project pay-offs, ambiguity
relates to uncertainty as to the probability measure governing those outcomes as well. In this paper, we
use the term ‘uncertainty’ to mean either risk or ambiguity or both. That is, uncertainty is comprised of
both risk and ambiguity. Weuse the terms ambiguity and “Knightian uncertainty” interchangeably.
2 See Epstein and Schneider (2010) for a review of the ambiguity literature.
3 Note that a manager’s ability to develop expectations regarding future investment pay-offs may also
be affected by the manager’s overconfidence. However, in the context of investment, we believe that
overconfidence is likely to work in the opposite direction as ambiguity. Specifically, we expect ambiguity
to decrease the manager’s precision of the pay-off distribution and thus lead to less investment. In contrast,
as stated in Gervais et al. (2011, p.1,738), “overconfidence captures the idea that individuals overestimate
the precision of their information or their ability to interpret that information when they make economic
decisions.” If overconfident managers overestimate the precision of their investment pay-off distribution, we
would expect overconfidence to lead to greater investment, biasing against our hypothesized results.
4 We also model cash holdings following Ozkan and Ozkan (2004) as an alternative analysis.
C
2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT