The Illinois Brick Damages Edifice: Demolition or Deconstruction?

AuthorGregory K. Leonard
PositionEconomist, Charles River Associates, Inc., and Editorial Board Vice Chair for Economics, Antitrust Law Journal
Pages315-339
THE ILLINOIS BRICK DAMAGES EDIFICE:
DEMOLITION OR DECONSTRUCTION?
G
REGORY
K. L
EONARD
*
When a young economist is introduced to the world of litigation consulting,
among the first overarching legal principles she learns is that the purpose of
compensatory damages, given that liability has been established, is to return
the plaintiff to the economic position it would have been in absent the defen-
dant’s unlawful conduct.
1
The compensatory principle appeals to economists,
who have a long tradition built around the welfare economics notions of
“compensating variation” and “equivalent variation”—measures of the change
in an individual’s income needed to maintain a given utility level in the face
of a change in the price or quality of one or more goods that the individual
consumes.
2
Later, however, when the eager young economist encounters antitrust liti-
gation, and specifically the framework for calculating damages in a price-
fixing case under Section 4 of the Clayton Act, confusion ensues. She is in-
formed that, given the Supreme Court’s Illinois Brick ruling, only direct pur-
chasers are entitled to recover damages in such cases and that these damages
take the form of overcharges on actual purchases.
3
Indirect purchasers, includ-
ing final consumers, are out of luck under federal law. But, the economist
asks, how does denying damages to indirect purchasers square with the idea
that compensatory damages should return injured parties to the position they
would have been in absent the challenged conduct? Well, she is told, limiting
damages to direct purchasers and basing direct purchaser damages on
overcharges avoids duplicate recovery, saves courts from the complex task of
determining the damages sustained by downstream entities in the distribution
* Economist, Charles River Associates, Inc., and Editorial Board Vice Chair for Economics,
Antitrust Law Journal.
1
Damage awards’ dual roles of compensation and deterrence are discussed below.
2
H
AL
R. V
ARIAN
, M
ICROECONOMIC
A
NALYSIS
161 (3d ed. 1992).
3
Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 728–29 (1977).
315
316
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
J
OURNAL
[Vol. 84
chain, and, by making antitrust litigation more effective, enhances deterrence.
4
But, the economist points out, the overcharge may not be a good measure of
the economic injury the direct purchaser actually sustained, a further apparent
departure from compensatory damages.
5
Yes, the economist is told, but over-
charge damages give direct purchasers a stronger incentive to sue and, any-
way, do not worry about indirect purchasers because a number of states have
enacted “Illinois Brick repealer” laws or otherwise allowed indirect purchas-
ers in those states to recover damages.
6
At this point, the young economist is
likely to decide that the framework for awarding damages in overcharge cases
in the United States is something of a mess and not the result of a thoughtful,
coherent design.
Economists are not alone in questioning how damages are calculated in
overcharge cases. Legal scholars and practitioners have also been troubled by
the divergence of the Illinois Brick framework from the compensatory princi-
ple, as well as the shortcomings of the defendant’s overcharge as an appropri-
ate measure of the actual damages.
7
These concerns are longstanding, dating
back to the Illinois Brick decision itself, which was controversial when issued
8
and motivated the enactment of overrides and other measures by state
lawmakers.
9
Despite various efforts to do away with Illinois Brick, its approach to how
damages are calculated in overcharge cases survives to the current day.
10
With
the Supreme Court’s recent Apple v. Pepper decision, however, another door
may have opened for reconsideration.
11
But, what should replace the Illinois
Brick framework? And what would the implications of replacing it be?
Part I discusses what economics has to say about the economic losses sus-
tained by downstream entities resulting from overcharges imposed by entities
at the top of a distribution chain and how the economic losses caused by the
4
See, e.g., ABA S
ECTION OF
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
, I
NDIRECT
P
URCHASER
L
ITIGATION
H
ANDBOOK
465–71 (2d ed. 2016).
5
To make matters worse, under Hanover Shoe, a defendant is prohibited from arguing that
the overcharges overstate the direct purchaser’s economic losses because the direct purchaser
passed on the overcharges to indirect purchasers. Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Mach.
Corp., 392 U.S. 481, 488–90 (1968).
6
ABA S
ECTION OF
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
,supra note 4, at 23–25.
7
For recent expressions of these concerns, see Andrew I. Gavil, Consumer Welfare Without
Consumers? Illinois Brick After Apple v. Pepper, 7 J. A
NTITRUST
E
NFORCEMENT
447 (2019), and
Herbert Hovenkamp, Apple v. Pepper: Rationalizing Antitrust’s Indirect Purchaser Rule, 120
C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. F
ORUM
14 (2020).
8
Hovenkamp, supra note 7, at 14.
9
Gavil, supra note 7, at 450.
10
For example, in 2007, the Antitrust Modernization Commission proposed substantial
changes to the way damages are calculated, including the overruling of Illinois Brick. A
NTITRUST
M
ODERNIZATION
C
OMM
N
, R
EPORT AND
R
ECOMMENDATIONS
267 (2007).
11
Gavil, supra note 7, at 44849.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT