The Identification and Proof of Horizontal Agreements under the Antitrust Laws

Published date01 March 1993
Date01 March 1993
DOI10.1177/0003603X9303800102
AuthorWilliam E. Kovacic
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Spring 1993
The identification and
proof
of
horizontal agreements under
the antitrust laws
BY WILLIAM E. KOVACIC*
I. Introduction
5
American antitrust law draws a crucial distinction between uni-
lateral and collective behavior. Restrictions on unilateral conduct,
effectuated mainly through the Sherman Act's prohibition against
monopolization and attempted monopolization.' are hardly lin-
important.s but they usually come into play only when the defen-
*Associate Professor, George Mason University
School
of
Law,
and
Of
Counsel to Bryan, Cave in Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR'S NOTE: I am grateful to Jonathan Baker and Kathryn Fenton
for many useful comments and discussions. I also thank the John M. Olin
Foundation and the Sarah Scaife Foundation for their support in the
preparation
of
this article.
15 U.S.C. §2.
2See Kovacic, Failed Expectations: The Troubled Past and Uncer-
tain Future
of
the Sherman Act as a Tool for Deconcentration, 74 IOWA
L.
REV.
1105 (1989).
e1993 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
6 The antitrust bulletin
dant
has
attained
considerable
stature
in the
market.!
On
the
whole, firms acting alone face relatively few antitrust risks unless
they have market power.
Although
some
commentators
have
argued
that
antitrust's
treatment
of
horizontal collective action is unduly harsh,' legal
doctrine and government enforcement policy view interfirm col-
laboration involving direct rivals with considerably greater skepti-
cism.>
In many instances
of
joint horizontal action, liability can be
established without regard to the defendants' market power.
For
example, it is irrelevant in cases brought under section I
of
the
Sherman
Act-
that the participants in a horizontal price-fixing
arrangement had little genuine prospect
of
affecting price through
their joint efforts to restrict
output.'
Indeed, when detected, such
conduct frequently results in criminal prosecution.!
See ABA
ANTITRUST
SECTION,
ANTITRUST
LAW
DEVELOPMENTS
212-18,262-67 (3ded.
1992).
4See Jorde &Teece, Innovation, Cooperation, and Antitrust, in
ANTITRUST,
INNOVATION,
AND
COMPETITIVENESS
47 (T. M. Jorde &D. J.
Teece eds., 1992); Demsetz, How Many Cheers
for
Antitrust's
100
Years? 30
ECON.
INQUIRY
207 (1992).
For a discussion of the grounds on
which
antitrust treats collective
conduct less favorably than unilateral conduct, see 6 P. E.
AREEDA,
ANTITRUST
LAW
9-12 (1986).
615
U.S.C.
§1.
7Cf. United States v, Reicher, 777 F. Supp. 901, 903 (D.N.M.
1991) (granting judgment of acquittal to government contractor who
enlisted assistance of a
sham
bidder as part of a scheme to rig bids for a
federal construction project; court concluded that the sham bidder lacked
capacity to perform contract and could not be deemed a "competitor" of
the defendant contractor, thus precluding the application of section 1 to
the challengedbehavior),
revd,
1992-2
Trade Cas.
(CCH)
, 70,083 (10th
Cir.1992).
See U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Enforcement Guidelines
for
International Operations, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH)
~
13,109,at §3.1 (Nov. 10, 1988).
Horizontal agreements : 7
Because characterizing action as collective can have powerful
consequences, antitrust litigants devote considerable attention
to determining whether the behavior in question stemmed from
an agreement and therefore implicated section
l's
ban
against
contracts,
combinations,
or conspiracies in restraint
of
trade.
Asubstantive legal command whose application hinges on the
existence
of
an agreement must solve two closely related prob-
lems. It must define the types
of
conduct that constitute an agree-
ment,
and
it
must
determine
the
means
by
which
such
an
agreement can be proven in a trial.
Antitrust disputes vary greatly according to the difficulty that
these problems pose. In some instances there is no need for elabo-
rate inquiry. The defendants collectively devise acollaborative
strategy and expressly exchange assurances that they will adhere
to a common course of action; they formulate plans and exchange
assurances directly in writing (for example, by circulating and
signing amemorandum), in face-to-face meetings of the partici-
pants, or in telephone conversations. The fact of collective efforts
to set pricing or output levels, divide markets, or allocate cus-
tomers emerges unmistakably through documents or testimony
from participants to the challenged arrangement.? When detected
by government enforcement officials, episodes
of
such behavior
rarely result in fully litigated trials. Instead, where the fact
of
col-
lective action and its purpose are easily ascertained, enforcement
initiatives ordinarily are concluded through plea agreements,
ci~il
consent orders, or damage settlements.w
The majority
of
cases, however, present analytical and eviden-
tiary challenges
of
much greater complexity. Such disputes come
in essentially three forms. In the first set of matters, the defen-
dants covertly but expressly exchange assurances, yet the trial
record contains no direct evidence (for example, aletter circulated
9See United States v. Alston, 974 F.2d 1206 (9th Cir. 1992); United
States v, All Star Indus., 962 F.2d 465 (5th Cir. 1992).
10 See L. B.
SCHWARTZ,
J. J.
FLYNN
&H.
FIRST,
FREE
ENTERPRISE
AND
ECONOMIC
ORGANIZATION:
ANTITRUST
438 (6th ed. 1983); Ginsburg, Non-
price Competition, 38
ANTITRUST
BULL.
83 (1993).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT