The Functions of a Minimal Legislature: Role Perceptions of Thai Legislators

Published date01 December 1972
DOI10.1177/106591297202500408
Date01 December 1972
AuthorMichael L. Mezey
Subject MatterArticles
686
THE
FUNCTIONS
OF
A
MINIMAL
LEGISLATURE:
ROLE
PERCEPTIONS
OF
THAI
LEGISLATORS
MICHAEL
L.
MEZEY
University
of
Hawaii
HE
STUDY
of
legislative
institutions
recently
has
moved
beyond
the
tradi-
g
tional
preoccupation
with
the
European
and
American
experiences
to
an
examination
of
legislatures
in
developing
political
systems.
Scholars
engaged
in
this
research
have
recognized
the
essential
point
that
simply
because
legislatures
in
these
nations
often
appear
to
be
marginal
to
political
decision-making,
they
are
not
necessarily
insignificant
to
the
political
systems
in
which
they
exist.1
In
the
discussion
that
follows,
the
general
characteristics
of
legislatures
in
developing
sys-
tems
will
be
sketched,
a
methodology
for
analyzing
such
institutions
will
be
sug-
gested,
and
an
analysis
of
one
such
legislature
-
the
National
Assembly
of
the
Kingdom
of
Thailand
-
will
be
attempted.
DEFINITIONS
AND
METHODOLOGY
Legislatures
in
developing
systems
are
generally
&dquo;minimal
legislatures.&dquo;
Al-
though
their
membership
is
popularly
elected
and
their
existence
and
prerogatives
are
formally
guaranteed
by
the
nation’s
constitution,
these
institutions
are,
in
the
final
analysis,
ultimately
subordinate
to
other
elements
in
the
political
system
in
whose
hands
actual
rule-making
power
resides.
In
such
a
system,
the
Government
rarely
loses
an
important
vote
in
the
legislature
and
such
a
defeat,
in
the
event
that
it
does
occur,
can
provoke
a
serious
constitutional
crisis.
The
Government
initiates
all
sigrtifica.nt
proposals
and
the
legislature
is
restricted
to
only
the
most
marginal
amendments.
Minimal
legislatures
are
distinguished
from
those
western
legislatures
that
are
equally
subordinate
in
the
decision-making
process
by
the
additional
characteristic
that
they
command
very
little
respect
or
support
from
the
population
at
large.2
2
There
is
a
persistent
belief
that
the
institution
is
simply
a
front
for
those
who
really
NOTE:
An
earlier
version
of
this
paper
was
presented
under
the
same
title
at
the
66th
Annual
Meeting
of
the
American
Political
Science
Association,
Los
Angeles,
September
1970.
The
research
for
this
study
was
completed
while
I
was
Visiting
Professor
in
the
Faculty
of
Political
Science,
Thammasat
University,
Bangkok.
My
stay
at
Thammasat
was
made
possible
by
a
Rockefeller
Foundation
University
Development
Program
grant
to
the
Uni-
versity
of
Virginia.
I
am
grateful
to
William
1.
Bacchus,
Saneh
Chamarik,
Montri
Chenvidyakam,
Paul
T.
David,
Gerald
Heeger,
Susan
G.
Mezey,
David
E.
Powell,
and
Astri
Surkhe
for
their
comments
on
earlier
drafts
of
this
manuscript.
1
The
best
of
this
research
is
contained
in
three
anthologies.
See,
Allan
Kornberg
and
Lloyd
D.
Musolf,
eds.,
Legislatures
in
Developmental
Perspective
(Durham:
Duke
University
Press,
1970);
Weston
H.
Agor,
ed.,
Latin
American
Legislatures:
Their
Role
and
Influ-
ence
(New
York:
Praeger,
1971) ;
and,
Allan
Kornberg,
ed.,
Legislatures
in
Comparative
Perspective
(New
York:
David
McKay,
forthcoming).
Also,
see
Raymond
Hopkins,
"The
Role
of
the
M.P.
in
Tanzania,"
American
Political
Science
Review,
64
(September
1970),
754-71.
2
My
view
of
what
"support"
means
is
strongly
influenced
by
David
Easton’s
explication
of the
concept.
See,
A
Systems
Analysis
of
Political
Life
(New
York:
Wiley,
1965),
especially
pp.
153-70,
209-11,
and
277,
288.
Also,
see
Gerhard
Loewenberg,
"The
Influence
of
Parliamentary
Behavior
on
Regime
Stability:
Some
Conceptual
Clarifications,"
Compara-
tive
Politics,
3
(January
1971),
177-200,
for
a
good
discussion
relating
legislative
per-
formance
to
system
stability
and
to
support
for
the
legislature.
687
hold
power;
leaders
of
the
legislature
are
not
taken
seriously
by
the
public
and
con-
sequently
when
such
legislatures
are
blatantly
manipulated,
dismantled,
or
circum-
vented,
such
actions
cause
no
general
public
outcry
but
rather
are
considered
part
of
the
usual
and
expected
course
of
political
events.
A
wide
variety
of
legislatures
can
be
described
in
these
terms.
Legislatures
dominated
by
the
Communist
party
fall
into
this
category
(North
Vietnam,
North
Korea)
as
do
legislatures
in
military-dominated
systems
(Burma,
South
Korea,
South
Vietnam,
Indonesia,
Cambodia),
systems
led
by
charismatic
leaders
(Egypt
under
Nasser,
Ghana
under
Nkrumah),
systems
dominated
by
an
inclusive
mass
party
(Tanzania
under
TANU,
Guinea
under
PDG,
Kenya
under
KANU),
or
systems
dominated
by
a
combination
of
professional
bureaucrats
and
military
leaders
(Thailand,
from
1969
to
1971,
and
Pakistan).
The
study
of
these
legislatures
requires
a
functional
approach.
Ironically,
it
was
functionalism
that
led
students
of
comparative
politics
away
from
legislatures
in
developing
systems.
Working
under
the
assumption
that
the
only
function
for
a
legislature
was
rule-making,
observers
of
non-western
systems
were
quick
to
discover
that
&dquo;the
formally
constituted
law-making
bodies
[had]
not
as
yet
become
the
focus
for
the
rule-making
function.
The
usual
practice
[was]
for
the
dominant
group
to
issue
essential
decrees
or
initiate
administrative
regulations.&dquo;
3 Attention
therefore
shifted
toward
the
study
of
these
&dquo;dominant
groups.&dquo;
The
analysis
of
minimal
legis-
latures
calls
for
a
return
to
the
functional
approach
which
assumes
that
sociological
phenomena
(e.g.,
structures,
roles,
institutional
patterns,
norms)
may
be
explained
by
the
part
that
they
play
in
meeting
the
demands
of
the
social
system
in
which
they
exist.4
Thus
it
should
be
assumed
that
legislatures
exist
and
persist
in
political
sys-
tems
because
they
perform
both
manifest
and
latent
functions
for
that
system.
Legislatures
may
then
be
compared
by
delineating
these
functions
for
each
particular
political
system.
A
wide
variety
of
data
may
be
employed
in
this
enterprise.5
The
history
of
legislative
institutions
in
a
nation
may
provide
an
indication
of
the
functions
which
the
legislature
has
traditionally
performed;
an
analysis
of
the
constitutional
struc-
ture
will
provide
a
formal
statement
of
legislative
functions;
direct
observation
of
legislative
behavior
as
well
as
informed
assessments
of
the
political
situation
may
lead
to
perceptive
statements
of
manifest
and
latent
functions.
In
this
analysis,
we
3
Lucian
Pye,
"The
Politics
of
Southeast
Asia,"
in
Gabriel
Almond
and
James
Coleman.
eds.,
The
Politics
of
the
Developing
Areas
(Princeton:
Princeton
University
Press,
1960),
p.
144.
4
This
view
of
functionalism
should
be
distinguished
from
structural-functional
analysis,
which
emphasizes
the
identification
of
certain
functions
as
necessary
and
sufficient
for
the
per-
sistence
of
all
social
systems.
My
view
of
functionalism
as
a
methodology
closely
follows
the
discussion
of
Robert
Merton,
Social
Theory
and
Social
Structure
(enlarged
ed.;
New
York:
Free
Press,
1968),
pp.
73-138.
A
good
introduction
to
functional
analysis
is
pro-
vided
by
William
Flanigan
and
Edward
Fogelman,
"Functional
Analysis,"
in
James
C.
Charlesworth,
ed.,
Contemporary
Political
Analysis
(New
York :
Free
Press,
1967),
pp.
72-86.
Also,
see
Ely
Chinoy,
Sociological
Perspective
(2nd
ed.;
New
York:
Random
House,
1968),
pp.
158-77.
See
Robert
A.
Packenham,
"Legislatures
and
Political
Devel-
opment,"
in Kornberg
and
Musolf,
op.
cit.,
pp.
523-46,
for
a
functional
analysis
of
the
Brazilian
National
Congress
as
well
as
some
suggestions
of
the
possible
functions
of
legis-
latures
in
some
other
developing
systems.
5
See
Merton,
op.
cit.,
pp.
104-9,
for
a
detailed
description
of
the
functionalist
research
meth-
odology.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT