The Foreign Exchange Origins of Japan's Economic Slump and Low Interest Liquidity Trap

Published date01 March 2001
AuthorKenichi Ohno,Ronald McKinnon
Date01 March 2001
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9701.00357
The Foreign Exchange Origins of
Japan’s Economic Slump and Low
Interest Liquidity Trap
Ronald McKinnon and Kenichi Ohno
1. JAPAN’S DOMESTIC ECONOMY IN THE 1990s
BEFORE considering the strong international influences on Japan’s
economy, let us sketch the evolution of Japan’s slump in the 1990s from
a purely domestic perspective.
When Japan’s bubble economy burst in 1991–92, the sharp fall in the stock
market and land values made a significant economic downturn – or at least a
period of sluggish growth (by Japanese standards) – inevitable. Bad loans in the
banking system, associated with the collapsing value of real estate and equity
collateral, proliferated and impaired bank capital. The sharp decline in household
wealth caused consumer expenditures to fall. Excess capacity induced business
firms to curtail investment. Such economic travail is hardly surprising when asset
bubbles burst.
More surprising is that, almost a decade later, Japan’s economy has yet to
recover. Figure 1 shows how sluggish Japanese GDP growth has become in the
1990s. Except for 1996 when annualised growth touched 5 per cent (more on this
below), GDP growth since 1991 has averaged less than 1 per cent per year – and
was sharply negative in 1998 with negligible growth in 1999. Yet, among
industrial countries, Japan had been the premier growth economy for the previous
four decades. With the world’s highest saving rates and seemingly endless
capacity to adapt to, and dramatically augment, the latest industrial technologies,
ßBlackwell Publishers Ltd 2001, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK
and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 279
RONALD McKINNON is Professor of Economics at Stanford University, California. KENICHI
OHNO is Professor at the National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies, Tokyo. The argument here
updates and extends their recent book, Dollar and Yen: Resolving Economic Conflict between the
United States and Japan (MIT Press, 1997; Japanese translation, Nihon Keizai Shimbunsha, 1998).
But the book provides necessary supporting empirical and analytical detail. The authors would like
to thank Rishi Goyal of Stanford University for his research assistance. Akiyoshi Horiuchi of the
University of Tokyo, and Kunio Okina and Hiroshi Fujuki of the Bank of Japan, made helpful
comments – although they may not agree with the authors’ main argument.
Japan’s GDP grew at 6 to 12 per cent in the 1950s and 60s – and at a robust 3 to 5
per cent in the 1970s and 80s, when the rest of the industrial world was
comparatively stagnant. Moreover, these basic virtues of private industry and
thrift, and a highly skilled labour force with unmatched engineering capability in
hi-tech manufacturing, remain intact. However, throughout the 1990s into 2000,
domestic aggregate demand – both private investment and consumption – failed
to recover.
a. The Fiscal Response
On the fiscal side, the Japanese government responded with massive public
expenditure programmes designed to prime the pump of aggregate demand.
Consequently, Japan’s fiscal deficit in 1999 exceeded 10 per cent of GNP. Table
1 shows that Japanese government gross debt rose from 58.2 per cent of GDP in
1991 and the OECD projected it to increase to more than 114 per cent of GDP in
2000,
1
and 120 per cent in 2001. This upward trend is completely out of step with
other G-7 countries. Even Italy has succeeded in putting its similarly large debt
ratio on a downward trajectory (Table 1).
Offsetting this fiscal ‘expansion’, the yen appreciated sharply in 1994–95 –
peaking out at a highly overvalued 80 to the dollar in April 1995 – and depressed
both exports and private domestic investment. (More on the causes of this
FIGURE 1
Japan GDP Growth Rates
1
OECD Economic Outlook (December 1999, p. 226).
280 RONALD McKINNON AND KENICHI OHNO
ßBlackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
appreciation below.) However, in 1996 when the yen fell and became less
overvalued, output growth spurted to 5 per cent. Recovery seemed at hand.
In April 1997, believing that this fiscal pump priming had worked but
concerned with the out-of-control debt buildup, the government of the then Prime
Minister Ryutaro Hashimoto seized the opportunity to increase the general sales
tax from 3 to 5 per cent – and to close other tax loopholes. This tax increase sent
TABLE 1
General Government Gross Financial Liabilities
(As a percentage of nominal GDP)
Estimates and
Projections
1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
US 65.5 68.1 69.7 68.9 68.3 67.7 65.4 62.4 59.3 57.1 55.2
Japan* 58.2 59.8 63.0 69.4 76.0 80.6 84.7 97.3 105.4 114.1 122.1
Germany** 40.1 43.4 49.0 49.2 59.1 61.9 62.8 63.3 62.6 61.7 60.2
France 40.3 44.7 51.6 55.3 59.4 62.3 64.5 64.9 65.2 64.6 63.4
Italy 107.4 116.1 117.9 124.0 123.1 122.2 120.4 118.2 117.7 115.2 112.3
UK 40.1 46.9 56.2 53.7 58.9 58.5 58.9 56.4 54.0 51.2 48.6
Canada 80.9 88.2 96.8 98.0 99.2 98.9 94.1 91.7 86.9 82.5 78.5
Notes:
* Includes the debt of the Japan Railway Settlement Corporation and the National Forest Special Account from
1998 onwards.
** Includes the debt of the German Railways Fund from 1994 onwards and the Inherited Debt Fund from 1995
onwards.
Source: OECD Economic Outlook (December 1999, p. 226).
FIGURE 2
Japan: Consumption Expenditure
(Change from the same month of the previous year)
Sources: Management and Coordination Agency (overall real consumption expenditure); Department Stores
Association (department sales); Japan Automobile Dealers Association (new car sales).
FOREIGN EXCHANGE ORIGINS OF JAPAN’S SLUMP 281
ßBlackwell Publishers Ltd 2001

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT