THE FINANCIAL IMPACT OF LENDER‐OF‐LAST‐RESORT BORROWING FROM THE FEDERAL RESERVE DURING THE FINANCIAL CRISIS

Date01 June 2016
Published date01 June 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12092
THE FINANCIAL IMPACT OF LENDER-OF-LAST-RESORT BORROWING
FROM THE FEDERAL RESERVE DURING THE FINANCIAL CRISIS
Benjamin M. Blau
Utah State University
Scott E. Hein
Texas Tech University
Ryan J. Whitby
Utah State University
Abstract
The U.S. Federal Reserve (Fed) was reluctant to release the names of rms that
borrowed, and the amounts borrowed, from the emergency loan facilities during the
nancial crisis. We show that when the details of this information were nally made
public by the Fed, there was no stock market reaction, contrary to the thought that this
was valuable information. However, further investigation shows that stock returns for
publicly traded borrowing institutions declined signicantly and almost immediately
after the Fed borrowing was initiated, although the information had not been made
public by the Fed at the time. The underperformance of borrowing institutions was
greatest for those that received the largest loans or had the largest amount of loans
outstanding. This evidence is consistent with the idea that investors were able to trade on
the information about the Feds emergency loan program, although the Fed purposely
tried to keep the information private.
JEL Classification: G01, G10, G20, G28
I. Introduction
Like much of the existing literature in nance, the broad purpose of this research is to
investigate how nancial markets incorporate information into market prices. A key
distinguishing feature of our study is that we examine how private (vis-
a-vis public)
information ows into stock prices. In our investigation, we uncover evidence that the
stock prices of institutions that borrowed from the U.S. Federal Reserve (Fed) during
the recent nancialcrisis seemed to quickly incorporateinformation about the details ofthe
lending that the Fed attempted to keep private. Specically, borrowing rms are foundto
suffer stock price declines almost immediately after the rm borrowed from the Fed.
We acknowledge the helpful comments of Kyle Allen, Will Armstrong, Frank Caliendo, Laura Cardella,
George Cashman, Jack Cooney, Ken Cyree, Bob DeYoung, Mike Erickson, Scott Findley, Scott Frame, Robert
Jordan, Junyoup Lee, Jeff Mercer, Mark Moore, Brett Myers, Dan Thornton, Paula Tkac, Larry Wall, David
Wheelock, Matthew Whitledge, Arthur Wilmarth, Drew Winters, and two anonymous referees.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXXIX, No. 2 Pages 179206 Summer 2016
179
© 2016 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
During the past two decades, there has been a movement by central banks around
the world to increase the level of transparency in their monetary policy actions and thus
provide more public information about their actions (Svensson 1999; Geraats 2002;
Blinder et al. 2008). For instance, central banks in Australia, Brazil, Canada, Chile,
Mexico, New Zealand, Spain, and Sweden adopted the policy of publishing ination
targets during the 1990s. Crowe (2010) shows empirically that transparent policies, such
as ination targeting, provide economic benets by reducing information asymmetries
between policy makers and economic agents. A survey in Fry et al. (2000) reveals that
nearly three-fourths of central banks around the world consider transparency a vital
componentof their policy framework.
Similar to other central banks, the Fed has recently increased the transparency of
its monetary policy by providing more public information to market participants.
1
For
example, the Fed now announces its target for the federal funds rate, whereas it did not
provide this explicit information to the public until the mid-1980s. More recently, instead
of stating only a given range, the Fed now states an explicit target ination rate of 2%.
Although the Feds level of transparency and public information provision about
monetary policy decisions have been increasing, the Fed was reluctant to release to the
public information about the specic borrowers from its emergency lending programs
during the recent nancial crisis, releasing neither the identity nor the amount borrowed
either incrementally or entirely.
The motivation for withholding information from the public about the identity of
the borrowers and the amount borrowed appears to have been driven by fear that the news
could have caused a bank runon the borrowing institution. Knowledge of a banks
participation in either of the Feds lender-of-last-resort facilities could have provided an
unfavorable signal to both nancial markets and depositors, which could have reduced
public condence in the stability of the participating bank.
2
Empirical research tends to
support this contention of a stigma associated with borrowing from the Fed (Peristiani
1998; Furne 2001; Darrat et al. 2004; Armantier et al. 2011).
As anecdotal evidence of the idea that the Fed wants to increase transparency while
carefully managing the stigma associated with participation in the various Fed lending
programs, Chairman Ben Bernanke testied before the U.S. Congress in February 2010:
We are also prepared to support legislation that would require the release of the identities
of the rms that participated in each special [emergency lending] facility after an
appropriate delay. It is important that the release occur after a lag that is sufciently
long that investors will not view an institutions use of one of the facilities as a possible
indication of ongoing nancial problems, thereby undermining market condence in the
1
Although Thornton (2003) questions the wisdom of seeking to achieve increased monetary policy
transparency as an end goal, recent speeches have highlighted the importance of Fed transparency (see, e.g., http://
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100525a.htm) in the eyes of many. Blinder et al. (2008)
further document moves by the Fed to enhance transparency.
2
The Fed, as well as the federal government, instituted a variety of emergency lending programs during the
nancial crisis aimed at both depository and nondepository institutions. The analysis in this study focuses on Fed
programs that are similar in nature to the lender-of-last-resort funding. Cyree, Grifths, and Winters (2013)
examine Fed emergency lending programs aside from the two we investigate.
180 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT