The evolution of support for democratic regime principles and its alternatives

Published date01 February 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/pa.1644
Date01 February 2017
AuthorCindy Steenekamp,Pierre Toit
SPECIAL ISSUE PAPER
The evolution of support for democratic regime principles and
its alternatives*
Cindy Steenekamp
1
|Pierre du Toit
2
1
Stellenbosch University, Centre for
International and Comparative Politics,
Matieland, South Africa
2
Department of Political Science, Stellenbosch
University, Matieland, South Africa
Correspondence
Cindy Steenekamp, Centre for International
and Comparative Politics, Stellenbosch
University, Private Bag X1, Matieland, 7602
South Africa.
Email: cindylee@sun.ac.za
The aim of this paper is to examine the claim that most people in almost every country world-
wide prefer democracy over other types of regimesagainst new data, so as to add to the global
map of popular perceptions about their support for various regime types. We describe measured
changes in levels of public support in 49 countries over four waves of the World Values Survey on
three levels: country specific, regionalcontinental, and global. We found that levels of support
for democracy are high and stable across most parts of the world; however, support for various
alternate (authoritarian) regime types is steadily increasing and could threaten the extent to
which democratic values are entrenched, especially in younger democracies. We conclude with
an overview of some of the factors that could plausibly shape such perceptions at the level of
the general citizenry.
1|INTRODUCTION
Confidence in the virtues of democracy and about its popular endorse-
ment as a regime type in competition with its alternatives is wavering
among some opinion leaders (Plattner, 2015, pp. 510), and possibly
also among the general citizenry of democracies and nondemocracies
alike. This is not the first time that concerns about this regime type
have gained expression, and the contemporary mood bears resem-
blance to some of the earliest doubts about the inherent resilience of
democratic regimes.
It is generally understood that in democratic regimes, the final,
decisive decisionmaking power in public affairs is vested not with
the rulers but with the ruled. This defining structural arrangement is
legitimized mostly from any combination of either tradition, rational
deliberation, and/or ideology. This structural distribution of power also
gives rise to another defining feature of the process of democracy:
support is acquired by persuading and not by commanding (Finer,
1997, pp. 4647).
Whether institutional rules could be found to provide a stable
basis for democratic regimes has been in doubt from its early appli-
cation in the Greek polis, with the first and primary set of weak-
nesses were seen to derive from inherent structural design
features. In the classic typology of regimes presented by Aristotle,
every regime type, including that of democracy, was presented in
both its virtuous form, where rule was to the benefit of all, and in
its degenerate form, where rulers exercised power to their own ben-
efit. In the case of democracy, degeneration was associated with
anarchy and chaos.
The second weakness was identified within the democratic pro-
cess. Democratic rulers are to proceed with popular support gained
through persuasion. This, in turn, is a function of the effective commu-
nication of arguments for or against certain policy choices over others.
Constructing telling arguments from given facts that are interwoven
into popular beliefs and convictions, and skillfully presented as being
the most beneficial and most attractive choice, is the practice and art
of rhetoric. Democratic pessimists held the view from early on that
those citizens over whom democrats rule are peculiarly vulnerable to
exploitation through devious rhetoric, which undermines the original
structural distribution of power between rulers and those over whom
they rule.
Taken together, the viability of democratic regimes was consid-
ered with some apprehension, given that many such poleis had
succumbed to their degenerate form (Finer, 1997, pp. 382383). In
the words of S.E. Finer (1997, p. 46, 47), the following assessment
prevailed until about two centuries ago: For rhetoric read demagogy,
for persuasion read corruption, pressure, intimidation, and falsification
of the vote. For meetings and assemblies, read tumult and riot. For
mature deliberation through a set of revising institutions, read self
division, inconstancy, slowness, and legislative and administrative stul-
tification. And for elections read factional plots and intrigues. These
featureswere what gave the term Republica bad name, but made
Democracyan object of sheer horror.
*This joint research project was supported by the Marianne and Marcus
Wallenberg Foundation in Sweden. The authors gratefully acknowledge their
financial support (MMW2012.0215).
Received: 12 December 2016 Accepted: 30 December 2016
DOI 10.1002/pa.1644
J Public Affairs. 2017;17:e1644.
https://doi.org/10.1002/pa.1644
Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/pa 1of12

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT