The European Court of Justice and the More Economic Approach to EU Competition Law—Is the Tide Turning?

AuthorAnne C. Witt
Date01 June 2019
DOI10.1177/0003603X19844637
Published date01 June 2019
Subject MatterArticles
Article
The European Court of Justice
and the More Economic
Approach to EU Competition
Law—Is the Tide Turning?
Anne C. Witt*
Abstract
In the late 1990s, the European Commission embarked on a mission to bring EU competition policy
more into line with contemporary economic theory. Over a period of ten years, it systematically
revised key legal concepts of all three pillars of EU competition law. Most importantly, it adopted the
consumer welfare aim, revised its understanding of competitive harm and countervailing effects
accordingly, and committed itself to carrying out more in-depth assessments of the investigated
conduct’s effects instead of relying on form-based presumptions of illegality. Initially, many tenets of
the more economic approach were in conflict with the case law of the European Court of Justice,
which had a broader understanding of the aims of EU competition law. However, after a few initial
set-backs for the Commission, several recent judgments in cases such as MEO,Intel,Post Danmark I,
and Cartes Bancaires suggest that the Court’s understanding of EU competition law is evolving and that
it is willing to embrace at least a few of the Commission’s revised principles. In particular, it is adopting
a more effects-based approach to assessing business conduct and is cautiously curbing its former
concept of harm in exclusionary situations. At the same time, however, it continues to adhere to
many of its former freedom- and fairness-based principles, so that a number of uncertainties and
inconsistencies remain.
Keywords
EU competition law, economic theory, consumer welfare, economic freedom, fairness, effects-based
analysis, form-based presumptions
I. Introduction
Over the past twenty years, the European Commission has radically reformed the way in which it
interprets and enforces the EU competition rules addressed to undertakings. It designed a new enforce-
ment system for Articles 101 and 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
*Associate Professor, Leicester Law School, University of Leicester, Leicester, UK
Corresponding Author:
Anne C. Witt, Leicester Law School, University of Leicester, Leicester LE1 7RH, UK.
Email: anne.witt@le.ac.uk
The Antitrust Bulletin
2019, Vol. 64(2) 172-213
ªThe Author(s) 2019
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0003603X19844637
journals.sagepub.com/home/abx
(TFEU),
1
which abolished the burdensome notification requirement for potentially anticompetitive
agreements and decentralized the enforcement of Article 101.
2
It created a leniency program to
enhance the detection of cartel infringements
3
and introduced a settlement procedure.
4
In addition
to these important procedural changes, the Commission also fundamentally revised its interpretation of
the substantive prohibition rules by introducing what has becom e known as the “more economic
approach” to EU competition law. The more economic approach is premised on the consumer welfare
aim, welfare-based concepts of harm and countervailing effects, and the idea that legal presumptions
of legality or illegality should only be used sparingly, so that, with a few exceptions, business conduct
should not be prohibited as anticompetitive without prior in-depth economic assessment of the inves-
tigated conduct’s actual effects on competition and consumer welfare.
Many of these changes are reminiscent, in substance, of the changes that the Chicago Revolution
triggered in the interpretation of U.S. antitrust law from the late 1970s onwards.
5
However, there is one
important difference. In the United States, it was the judiciary, in particular the U.S. Supreme Court,
which brought about this paradigm shift, having been swayed by the theories of the then up and coming
Chicago School.
6
In Europe, by contrast, it was the key enforcement body, namely, the European
Commission, that initiated and implemented these changes by means of soft law instruments and
decisional practice, around twenty years after the U.S. Antitrust Revolution.
This contribution argues that many of the changes introduced by the Commission’s more economic
approach initially ran counter the European Court of Justice’s interpretation of the substantive com-
petition rules, compelling the Commission to introduce the more economic approach to Article 102, in
particular, in a remarkably roundabout way. However, after several years of resistance, and under the
guidance of a more economically inclined Advocate General, a number of recent cases, such as Post
Danmark I,
7
Intel,
8
MEO,
9
Allianz Hung ´
aria,
10
and Cartes Bancaires,
11
signal a shift in the Court’s
attitude and a greater willingness to embrace key principles advocated by the Commission’s more
economic approach, in particular the welfare- and effects-based approach to assessing anticompetitive
conduct.
The aim of this contribution is to demonstrate the tensions that initially existed between the
Commission’s more economic approach and the case law, and to examine to what extent these
differences have now been eliminated. Section II sets the scene for this analysis by briefly explaining
1. Consolidated Version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU), 2012 O.J. (C 326/47). Unless
otherwise specified, the Articles cited in this contribution are those of the TFEU.
2. White Paper on modernisation of the rules implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty, 1999 O.J. (C 132/1), followed
by the Commission’s Proposal for a Council Regulation on the implementation of the rules on competition laid down in
Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty, 2000 O.J. (C 365 E/284), resulti ng in Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 on the
implementation of the rules on competition laid down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty, 2003 O.J. (L1/1).
3. Notice on the non-imposition or reduction of fines in cartel cases, 1996 O.J. (C 207/4), which has since been replaced by the
2006 Notice on immunity from fines and reduction of fines in cartel cases, 2006 O.J. (C 298/17).
4. Commission Regulation (EC) No 773/2004 relating to the conduct of proceedings by the Commission pursuant to Articles
81 and 82 of the EC Treaty, 2004 O.J. (L 123/18).
5. For a brief historical overview, see,e.g., Eleanor M. Fox & Lawrence A. Sullivan, Antitrust—Retrospective and
Prospective: Where Are We Coming From? Where Are We Going? 62 N.Y.U. L. REV. 336 (1987); William E Kovacic
& Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking 14 JEP 43 (2000).
6. From the late 1970s onwards, the U.S. Supreme Court overruled a number of precedents that were no longer deemed in line
with economic theory, e.g., in Continental T. V., Inc v. GTE Sylvania Inc, 433 U.S. 36 (1977); State Oil v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3
(1997); Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc v. PSKS, Inc, 127 S. Ct. 2705 (2007).
7. C-209/10, Post Danmark A/S v. Konkurrencera
˚det, ECLI: EU: C:2012:172 (hereafter, “Post Danmark I”).
8. C-413/14P, Intel Corp. v. Commission, ECLI: EU: C:2017:632.
9. C-525/16, MEO – Servic¸os de Comunicac¸o
˜es e Multim´edia SA v Autoridade da Concorreˆncia, ECLI: EU: C:2018:270.
10. C-32/11, Allianz Hung ´aria Biztos´ıt´o Zrt. and Others v. Gazdas ´agi Versenyhivatal, ECLI: EU: C:2013:160.
11. C-67/13 P,Groupement des cartes bancaires v. Commission, ECLI: EU: C:2014:2204.
Witt 173
the key changes introduced by the Commission’s more economic approach. Section III examines the
discrepancies that originally existed between the Commission’s revised interpretation and the case law
of the European Court of Justice. Section IV discusses several recent judgments that indicate that the
Court’s position is evolving. Section V analyzes these developments and argues that, while the Court
has embraced a number of the Commission’s economic principles, there remains a fair amount of
uncertainty and inconsistency. Section VI provides concluding remarks.
II. The European Commission’s More Economic Approach to EU
Competition Law
A. Background and Process
In the mid-1990s, the European Commission embarked on a comprehensive process of revising core
substantive principles of EU competition law, with the aim of elevating EU competition policy from its
former “legalistic approach” to one “based on sound economic principles.”
12
This journey spanned the
better part of fifteen years.
13
The Commission began with the review of Article 101,
14
moved on to EU
merger law in the early 2000s,
15
and concluded the process with the reform of Article 102 in 2009.
16
While these are three separate prohibition provisions that target different types of conduct,
17
they share
many core concepts. In particular, they pursue the same legal objective.
The Commission’s reform process sought to address increasingly vocal criticism that EU compe-
tition law was out of touch with economic reality and learning. Its approach to assessing vertical
relationships was deemed especially outdated. In particular, it was criticized for considering the
exclusion of competitors sufficient to make business conduct anticompetitive, rather than making this
finding dependent on whether such exclusion also had a detrimental effect on consumer welfare, which
U.S. antitrust law has required since the late 1970s.
18
Another key criticism was that EU competition
12. See, e.g., the publications and speeches of former Commissioner for Competition Policy: Mario Monti, A Competition
Policy for Today and Tomorrow, 23 W. COMP. 1 (2000); Antitrust in the US and Europe: A History of Convergence, Speech
at the General Counsel Roundtable, American Bar Association (Washington, DC, Nov. 14, 2001); EU Competition Policy,
Fordham Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy (New York, October 31, 2002), amongst many
others. The speeches are available at: www.ec.europa.eu/competition/speeches.
13. For a more detailed account of the process, see AW
ITT,THE MORE ECONOMIC APPROACH TO EU ANTITRUST LAW ch. 1–3
(2016).
14. Green Paper on Vertical Restraints in EC Competition Policy, COM(96) 721.
15. Green Paper on the Review of Council Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89, COM(2001) 745.
16. Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionary
conduct by dominant undertakings (hereafter, “Guidance on Article 102”), 2009 O.J. (C 45/7).
17. There are three substantive prohibition provisions: Article 101 TFEU, prohibiting agreements that have the object or effect
of restricting competition (formerly Article 81 EC/85 EEC); Article 102 TFEU, prohibiting the abuse of a dominant position
(formerly Article 82 EC/86 EEC); and Article 2(3) of Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the
control of concentrations between undertakings (hereafter, “EU Merger Regulation”), 2004 O.J. (L 24/1), formerly Council
Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89 of 21 December 1989 on the control of concentrations between undertakings, 1989 O.J.
(L 395/1).
18. See, e.g., John Vickers, Abuse of Market Power, 115 ECON. J. 244 (2005); John Kallaugher & Brian Sher, Rebates Revisited:
Anti-Competitive Effects and Exclusionary Abuse Under Article 82, 25 E.C.L.R. 263 (2004); Derek Ridyard, Exclusionary
Pricing and Price Discrimination Abuses Under Article 82—An Economic Analysis, 23 E.C.L.R. 286 (2002); William
Kolasky, Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It’s a Long Way from Chicago to Brussels,10G
EO.MASON L. R. 533
(2002); David S. Evans, The New Trustbusters, Brussels and Washington May Part Ways,81FOREIGN AFFAIRS 14 (2002);
Donna E. Patterson & Carl Shapiro, Transatlantic Divergence in GE/Honeywell: Causes and Lessons,16A
NTITRUST 18
(2001); Gary Becker, What US Courts Could Teach Europe’s Trust Busters,B
US.WK., Aug. 6, 2001, at 20; Barry Hawk,
System Failure: Vertical Restraints and EC Competition Law,32C.M.L.R
EV. 973 (1995); Valentine Korah, EEC
Competition Policy—Legal Form or Economic Efficiency, 39 C.L.P. 85 (1986), amongst many others.
174 The Antitrust Bulletin 64(2)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT