The Efficient Queue and the Case Against Dynamic Pricing

AuthorRamsi A. Woodcock
PositionAssistant Professor, University of Kentucky Rosenberg College of Law, Secondary Appointment, Department of Management, University of Kentucky Gatton College of Business and Economics
Pages1759-1797
1759
The Efficient Queue and
the Case Against Dynamic Pricing
Ramsi A. Woodcock*
ABSTRACT: From surge pricing by Uber to last-minute fare increases by
airlines, the use of price hikes to determine who should gain access to scarce
resources has swept the business world in recent years, enabled by the easy
access to information on what consumers are willing to pay, and the power of
algorithms to act on that information, that characterize the information age.
This practice, often euphemistically called dynamic pricing, has been defended
on the ground that higher prices are required to equilibrate supply and
demand. Lower prices, the argument goes, would lead to wasteful queuing.
In fact, the same technological advances that have enabled dynamic pricing
have also driven the cost of queuing nearly to zero, by allowing consumers to
place orders online, which amounts to standing on instantaneously-self-
clearing queues. Today, firms engage in dynamic pricing not because the
practice is better at rationing access to scarce resources, but because charging
higher prices is more profitable. Antitrust enforcers do not normally prosecute
the charging of high prices, but they have an opportunity to do so here, because
the harmfulness of dynamic pricing to consumers is clear and the remedy
—prohibiting dynamic pricing—would be relatively easy to administer.
I.INTRODUCTION ........................................................................... 1760
II.WELFARE EFFECTS AND ANTITRUST CONSEQUENCES ................. 1766
A.DYNAMIC PRICING AND ITS SPREAD ........................................ 1766
B.EXPLOITING AN ANTITRUST LOOPHOLE TO HARM
CONSUMERS .......................................................................... 1770
C.THE CASE FOR PER SE ILLEGALITY UNDER THE ANTITRUST
LAWS .................................................................................... 1774
*
Assistant Professor, University of Kentucky Rosenberg College of Law, Secondary
Appointment, Department of Management, University of Kentucky Gatton College of Business
and Economics. Harry First, Niklas Dürr, and participants at the 13th Academic Society for
Competition Law Conference at New York University School of Law, a May 2018 meeting of the
Mannheim Competition Policy Forum at the University of Mannheim, and a May 2018 CMA
Academy session at the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority, provided helpful
comments.
1760 IOWA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 105:1759
III.THE ALLOCATION PROBLEM ....................................................... 1782
A.DYNAMIC PRICING AS RATIONING WITH PRICE ........................ 1782
B.THE WEAKNESS OF THE CASE FOR RATIONING WITH PRICE ...... 1784
1.Willingness to Pay vs. Place in Line as Proxies
for Desire ..................................................................... 1784
2.Queues as Markets and Markets as Queues .............. 1787
C.THE LOW COST OF QUEUING IN THE INFORMATION AGE ......... 1789
IV.BEYOND DYNAMIC PRICING ......................................................... 1793
V. CONCLUSION .............................................................................. 1796
I. INTRODUCTION
Generations of introductory economics students have been taught that
prices clear markets, ensuring that the number of units of a good or service
demanded by consumers precisely equals the number of units supplied.1 And
yet the real world has always been rather obviously messier, as anyone who has
ever waited on line for a table at a restaurant, or found a child’s favorite toy
sold out at Christmas, can attest. Firms sometimes accidentally set their prices
considerably below the level required to equilibrate supply and demand,
resulting in too many buyers given available supply, because firms have always
lacked sufficient information to identify that magic market-clearing price with
certainty.2 The archetypical example of undershooting is the old Communist
state-run enterprise, which charged prices so low that anyone could buy,
leading to interminable lines.3 But underpricing has always been pervasive in
all capitalist countries as well, though to a far lesser degree, with waiting lists,
preordering, reservations systems, sold out notices, and indeed lines a familiar
experience for shoppers everywhere.4
Waiting lists, preordering and the like are species of the same basic
solution to the problem of how to ration a resource for which price has been
set too low to equilibrate supply with demand. That solution is queuing, the
granting of access based on the principle of first-come-first-served.5
1. See, e.g., HAL R. VARIAN, INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS: A MODERN APPROACH
289–90 (7th ed. 2006) (“The equilibrium price of a good is that price where the supply of the
good equals the demand. Geometrically, this is the price where the demand and the supply curves
cross.”).
2. See STEVEN ORLA KIMBROUGH, AGENTS, GAMES, AND EVOLUTION: STRATEGIES AT WORK
AND PLAY 193–98 (2011).
3. See JÁNOS KORNAI, THE SOCIALIST SYSTEM: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF COMMUNISM 287
(1992).
4. See Andrew Ross Sorkin, Hurricane Price Gouging Is Despicable, Right? Not to Some Economists,
N.Y. TIMES (Sept. 11, 2017), https://www.nytimes.com/2017/09/11/business/hurricane-price-
gouging.html [https://perma.cc/62NX-VK2C].
5. See Yoram Barzel, A Theory of Rationing by Waiting, 17 J.L. & ECON. 73, 73, 75 (1974).
2020] THE EFFICIENT QUEUE AND DYNAMIC PRICING 1761
Economists have long lamented the waste associated with queuing, from time
spent on lines that could have been spent on labor, to the resources wasted
by firms in managing reservations systems.6 The arrival of the information age
has therefore seemed a godsend, giving firms the power to put an end to
shortages and queuing by allowing firms at last to identify the market-clearing
price. Vast amounts of data on consumers, generated by firms themselves
based on records of their own interactions with consumers, and purchased
from third-party data aggregators, allow firms to determine how many
consumers are able to pay each possible price for a product, and therefore to
identify the price that just clears the market.7
Charging that price empties all lines, sending a magical signal to
consumers that encourages hopefuls who cannot afford the price to disperse,
and beckons those who can afford the price to come forth to buy.8 In this
spirit, economists have celebrated the spread in recent years of dynamic
pricing throughout the economy, from Disney World, which now uses higher
prices to reduce lines during periods of peak demand, to commuter highways,
which are dynamically pricing their fast lanes, to cities considering charging
a “congestion price” for access to downtown, to Uber, which uses surge pricing
to handle the rush after concerts and games, and to Amazon, which varies
prices on thousands of products hundreds of times per day.9
The irony of the information age is that at the same time that information
makes the finding of market-clearing prices easier, information also reduces
the waste associated with queuing, eliminating the problem that the charging
of market-clearing prices was intended to solve. The information age has
greatly reduced the cost of selling based on the principle of first-come-first-
served, by allowing consumers to determine instantaneously, via online retail
platforms, whether an item is available for purchase or sold out. As an
increasing amount of commerce moves online from brick-and-mortar
6. See id. at 73; VARIAN, supra note 1, at 308.
7. See Akiva A. Miller, What Do We Worry About When We Worry About Price Discrimination? The
Law and Ethics of Using Personal Information for Pricing, 19 J. TECH. L. & POLY 41, 44–54 (2014).
8. See VARIAN, supra note 1, at 7–8, 306–07 (“At this price, each consumer who is willing to
pay at least p* is able to find an apartment to rent, and each landlord will be able to rent
apartments at the going market price. Neither the consumers nor the landlords have any reason
to change their behavior.”).
9. Sorkin, supra note 4; see Winnie Hu, Congestion Pricing Falters in New York , Again, N.Y.
TIMES (Mar. 31, 2018), https://www.nytimes.com/2018/03/31/nyregion/congestion-pricing-
new-york.html [https://perma.cc/Z7KQ-6454]; S.K., Disney Discovers Peak Pricing, ECONOMIST
(Feb. 29, 2016), https://www.economist.com/free-exchange/2016/02/29/disney-discovers-
peak-pricing [https://perma.cc/UP8A-3XWM]; Ben Popper, Uber Surge Pricing: Sound Eco nomic
Theory, Bad Business Practice, VERGE (Dec. 18, 2013, 11:34 AM), https://www.theverge.com/2013
/12/18/5221428/uber-surge -pricing-vs- price-gougin g-law [https://perma.cc/CH6D-J6DM];
Harry Wallop, How Online Giants Like Amazon Can Rip You off by Changing Prices up to 300 Times a
Year (And if You’re Rich, Some Websites Could Soon Charge You Even More!), DAILY MAIL, http://
www.dailymail.co.uk/~/article-4935422/index.html [https://perma.cc/X2RT-8NZZ] (last
updated Oct. 2, 2017, 7:56 AM).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT