The Effects of Economic Sanctions on Foreign Asset Expropriation

AuthorHoon Lee,David Lektzian,Glen Biglaiser
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00220027221118250
Published date01 February 2023
Date01 February 2023
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Journal of Conf‌lict Resolution
2023, Vol. 67(2-3) 266296
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00220027221118250
journals.sagepub.com/home/jcr
The Effects of Economic
Sanctions on Foreign Asset
Expropriation
Hoon Lee
1
, David Lektzian
1
, and Glen Biglaiser
2
Abstract
Studies suggest that home countries impose economic sanctions following host sta te
expropriation of home f‌irms. However, and not addressed in the empirical literature, is
the possibility that sanctions lead targeted countries to nationalize f‌irms from sender
countries. Using bilateral expropriation data from 1985 to 2010, and controlling for
endogeneity issues, we f‌ind that sanctions signif‌icantly increase expropriation risk,
encouraging targeted states to inf‌lict pain in a reciprocal manner on sender countries .
Expropriations also enable targeted nations to acquire economic assets from foreign
f‌irms, undermining the restricting goals of sanctioning states, and provide opportunities
for leaders to show political resolve at home by standing up to senders. Our results are
robust using monadic or dyadic data and different statistical methods, indicating an-
other sanction-busting strategy used by targeted countries.
Keywords
expropriation, economic sanctions, multinational corporations, sanction busting
Introduction
Since the end of World War II, the importance of economic sanctions has grown as a
tool sender countries use to change targeted statesforeign policy behavior (Hufbauer
1
Texas Tech University, Lubbock, TX, USA
2
University of North Texas, Denton, TX, USA
Corresponding Author:
Glen Biglaiser, Department of Political Science, University of North Texas, 1155 Union Circle #305340,
Denton, TX 76203, USA.
Email: gbiglais@gmail.com
et al. 2007;Morgan et al. 2014). During much the same time period, countries par-
ticularly from developing areas have expropriated assets of multinational corporations
(MNCs), whose headquaters are commonly located in developed countries. The link
between economic coercion and asset expropriation has not gone unnoticed in the
sanctions literature. Some case studies have identif‌ied a relationship between na-
tionalization and economic sanctions (Lamrani 2013;Olson 1975;Schreiber 2011),
where sanctions serve as a legal remedy in response to expropriation (Drury 2005;Fisk
2000;Hufbauer et al. 2007). We consider the reverse scenario, where targeted countries
nationalize MNCs from sender countries as a reply to sanctions.
In the economic coercion literature, sender countries seek to inf‌lict high costs on
target states by restricting trade, foreign direct investment (FDI), and foreign
currency f‌lows.
1
In response, targeted countries use different strategies to limit
losses from sanctions, such as seeking alternate foreign trade partners or investors,
or incurring higher sovereign debt to replace lost capital (Early 2009,2015;
Lektzian and Biglaiser 2013). However, we anticipate that targeted countries may
also employ appropriation to bust sanctions. Although expro priation has decreased
relative to the 1960s and 1970s, when host countries appropriated more than
1600 foreign f‌irms, nationalization has witnessed a bit ofa comeback since the early
2000s with more than 200 f‌irms falling into state hands (Hajzler 2012,2014;Hajzler
and Rosborough 2016).
Targeted countries have incentives for expropriating sender nationsprivate f‌irms.
Appropriations of sender country f‌irms allow targeted countries to indirectly inf‌lict pain
on sanctioning states. Nationalization, especially in natural resource sectors, where
investments require large initial capital infusions, produce signif‌icant losses for MNCs
and their shareholders in sender countries (Kobrin 1980,1984). Expropriations without
adequate compensation, which are illegal under international law, can be interpreted by
the targeted state as a countermeasure to sanctions, if the initial sanctions are deemed to
be illegal acts. In this case, expropriations could be seen as the target taking something
of proportional reciprocal value to the senders initial restrictions on the targetsf‌irms
(Alexander 2009;Happold and Eden 2016). By acting in a tit-for-tat manner with
sender countries, targeted states indirectly levy costs on senders that they could not
otherwise impose against more militarily and economically powerful countries.
Expropriations also bring economic benef‌its to targeted countries. Targeted states
obtain foreign f‌irm assets, spurring capital growth, as sanctioned states export products
previously traded by the MNCs or acquire goods they used to import, saving foreign
exchange earnings (Selden 1999). By accumulating capital via foreign asset expro-
priation, the targeted states also reduce currency crises resulting from sanctions (Peksen
and Son 2015). Nationalizations also increase resources for politicians to pay off
groups, enhancing the leaderships survival (Peksen 2017). Further, hardline policies
such as appropriation enable leaders in targeted countries to show political resolve at
home by standing up to sender nations, scoring political points with their domestic
constituents (Grossman, Manekin, and Margalit 2018;Kobrin 1987, 614). While
nationalizations could affect both domestic and foreign f‌irms, political leaders in
Lee et al. 267

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT