The Effects of “Early Offers” in Medical Malpractice Cases: Evidence from Texas

Date01 December 2009
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1740-1461.2009.01158.x
Published date01 December 2009
AuthorBernard Black,David A. Hyman,Charles Silver
The Effects of “Early Offers” in Medical
Malpractice Cases: Evidence from Texasjels_1158723..767
Bernard Black, David A. Hyman, and Charles Silver*
Medical malpractice litigation is costly and time consuming. Professor Jeffrey O’Connell,
with various co-authors, has long advocated “early offer” rules that would encourage defen-
dants to offer to settle for economic damages plus attorney fees, and punish plaintiffs who
refuse such offers. Using detailed closed claims data from Texas for 1988–2005, we simulate
the effects of these “early offers.” Under a base set of assumptions, early offers will sharply
reduce payouts in cases with small economic damages (under $100,000, all amounts in 1988
dollars); will moderately reduce payouts in currently tried cases with economic damages
from $100,000–$200,000 and would normally increase payouts (and therefore will not
be made) in tried (settled) cases with economic damages over $200,000 ($100,000). Overall,
we predict that early offers will be made in 72 percent of all cases, and will result in a 16
percent (20 percent) decline in payouts in tried (settled) cases. Almost all this effect comes
from the sharp decline in payouts in cases with small economic damages. Defense costs will
drop by roughly 60 percent (20 percent) in currently tried (settled) cases in which an early
offer is made, and by about 13 percent overall. An early offer program will have very different
effects on different types of plaintiffs, with especially large payout reductions for elderly and
deceased plaintiffs. An early offer program also overlaps substantially in its effects with a
statutory cap on noneconomic damages (which 26 states already have). Defendants in many
of these states have already realized large reductions in payment of noneconomic damages;
the additional reductions from an early offer program are modest and would often affect
plaintiffs whose recoveries were already limited by damage caps. Our mixed results contrast
sharply with dramatic claims by O’Connell and co-authors, who predict 70 percent reduc-
tions in both payouts and defense costs. Their estimates reflect the compound effects of a
series of unreasonable assumptions.
I. Introduction
Critics of medical malpractice (med mal) litigation assert that it is slow, expensive, and
levies an unjustified “tort tax” on defendants. Similar criticisms apply to personal injury
*Address correspondence to Bernard Black; email: bblack@northwestern.edu. Black is Hayden W. Head Regents
Chair for Faculty Excellence, University of Texas Law School, and Professor of Finance, University of Texas, Red
McCombs School of Business; Hyman is Richard and Marie Corman Professor of Law and Professor of Medicine,
University of Illinois; Silver is McDonald Endowed Chair in Civil Procedure, University of Texas Law School.
We thank Jill Horwitz and participants in the 2008 Conference on Empirical Legal Studies, 2008 Midwest Law and
Economics Association Meeting, and workshops at Northwestern and University of Michigan Law Schools for helpful
comments, and Hyun Kim for superb research assistance.
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 6, Issue 4, 723–767, December 2009
723
litigation more generally. Because the overwhelming majority of cases settle, rules that
encourage faster settlement are an obvious strategy for improving the performance of the
tort system.
In this article, we analyze one important early settlement proposal, first made by
Professor Jeffrey O’Connell in 1982.1Under the current version of this “early offer” pro-
posal, defendants can offer to settle for full economic damages plus attorney fees, possibly
with a minimum damages offer in some cases. Plaintiffs who refuse the offer face a large
stick in the form of a higher burden of proof; the defendants are “making offers that can’t
be refused.”2Recent studies by O’Connell and co-authors estimate huge payout reductions
from such a program—on the order of a 70 percent drop in both payouts and defense
costs.3
We simulate the impact of an “O’Connell” early offer program on payouts. We use a
data set of all closed medical malpractice claims in Texas from 1988–2005 with payouts over
$25,000 (1988$).4We study both tried and settled cases, and find similar results for both sets
of cases. All amounts in this article are in 1988 dollars; multiply by 1.82 to convert to 2008
dollars.
Under a base set of assumptions, we estimate that an early offer program could
produce a 16 percent overall decline in payouts in currently tried cases, and a 20 percent
decline in settled cases. We explore sensitivity analyses how this estimate will vary depending
on program details and one’s assumptions. This decline in payouts will result primarily from
large payout reductions for plaintiffs with limited or no economic damages ($0–$100,000).
There will also be large variation in how an early offer program affects different plaintiff
groups, with large payout declines for elderly and deceased plaintiffs, limited effects on
employed adults in nondeath cases and on children, and almost no effect on baby cases.
There is also substantial overlap between the cases in which an early offer program will
reduce payouts and the cases in which a cap on noneconomic damages (adopted by 26 states)
already does so.
Defendants will make early offers only if they expect to gain by doing so. This means
that early offers will be made principally in cases with “small” economic damages ($0 to
$100,000). They may also be made in currently tried cases with economic damages from
$100,000–$200,000, depending on likelihood of liability and other case characteristics.
Early offers would generally produce higher payouts in tried (settled) cases if economic
1O’Connell (1982).
2Hence the title of Professor O’Connell’s initial article, which begins “Offers That Can’t Be Refused.” Id.
3Hersch et al. (2007); O’Connell and Born (2008); O’Connell and Robinette (2008).
4This article is one of a series using the Texas closed claims database to explore different aspects of medical
malpractice and personal injury litigation. Other pieces of this project include Black et al. (2005) (trends in overall
payouts); Hyman et al. (2007) (comparing jury verdicts with actual payouts); Zeiler etal. (2007) (physician policy
limits and out-of-pocket payments); Black et al. (2008) (analyzing defense costs in medical malpractice claims);
Hyman et al. (2009a) (estimating effect of various damages caps); and Hyman etal. (2009b) (analyzing effect of
insurer duty to settle).
724 Black et al.
damages are over $200,000 ($100,000), and thus will normally not be made in these cases.
Overall, we predict that early offers will be made in 72 percent of all cases, which represent
about 42 percent of current payout.
The 70 percent payout reductions estimated by O’Connell and co-authors reflect the
compound effects of a series of unreasonable assumptions. These include: (1) assuming no
minimum damages offer in many cases; (2) assuming that two-thirds of paid damages are
noneconomic (we estimate that noneconomic damages represent 40 percent (52 percent)
of payout in tried (settled) cases); (3) assuming that current payouts include full payment
of economic damages (they do not in many tried cases and are unlikely to in settled cases);
(4) treating a fee of 10 percent of economic damages as a market-clearing price for the
services of plaintiffs’ attorneys (it isn’t close); (5) ignoring plaintiffs’ out-of-pocket costs; (6)
ignoring the time value of money; and (7) assuming that liability is certain.
Defense costs will decline moderately. We estimate that defense costs will drop by
roughly 60 percent (20 percent) in currently tried (settled) cases that are resolved with an
early offer, or about 13 percent across all cases. This contrasts with O’Connell’s assumption
that defense costs will drop by 70 percent in both tried and settled cases.
Our approach and data set have important limitations. Our data come from a single
state, albeit a large one. Our simulations require a series of assumptions. For tried cases,
these include assumptions about how to allocate payouts to different components of
damages, equilibrium fee levels, and plaintiffs’ ex ante chances of winning at trial in cases
that they actually win ex post. For settled cases, we also need to estimate the economic and
noneconomic components of payouts. We believe, however, that our assumptions for both
tried and settled cases are far more realistic than O’Connell’s. Our simulation approach
ignores how an early offer program might affect which cases are brought, which are taken
to trial, and how they are tried. Note, too, that any payout reductions from an early offer
program are a wealth transfer, and not a direct social savings. We do not evaluate here the
efficiency implications of a change in payouts.
Section II provides background on the pretrial settlement process, and describes the
Texas medical malpractice data set and our simulation methodology. Section III discusses
our data set, and Section IV describes our simulation methodology for tried cases. Section
V analyzes how an early offer program will affect tried cases. Section VI extends the analysis
to settled cases. Section VII examines how an early offer program will affect different types
of plaintiffs. Section VIII examines how such a program will affect defense costs, total
defendant costs, plaintiff’s net recovery, and system efficiency. Section IX compares our
early offer results to those found by O’Connell and co-authors. Section X discusses some
implications of our findings. Section XI concludes.
HOV reply to this article in the next volume of this journal, and we then respond to
their reply.5We urge those interested in fully understanding the differences in assumptions
and analysis that drive the differences in results to read those two articles, as well as this one
and the original HOV article. In particular, our response contains a more extensive state-
ment of our assumptions, and how they differ from HOV, than is offered below.
5Hersch, O’Connell & Viscusi (forthcoming); Black, Hyman & Silver (forthcoming).
“Early Offers” in Medical Malpractice Cases 725

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT