The effect of trade secrets protection on disclosure of forward‐looking financial information

Date01 March 2020
Published date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12418
DOI: 10.1111/jbfa.12418
The effect of trade secrets protection on disclosure
of forward-looking financial information
Yan L i1Yutao Li2
1Faculty of Business and Economics, University
of Melbourne
2Dhillon School of Business, University of
Lethbridge
Correspondence
YutaoLi, Dhillon School of Business, University
ofLethbridge Calgary Campus, 345 – 6 Ave S.E.
Calgary,Alberta, Canada, T2G 4V1.
Email:yutao.li@uleth.ca
Fundinginformation
Universityof Lethbridge, Grant/Award Number:
CREDO2017-2019
Abstract
Using the recognition of the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine (IDD) by
US state courts as an exogenous shock to the risk of losing trade
secrets, this study examinesthe effects of trade secrets on disclosure
of forward-looking financial information. We find that management
earnings forecast frequency and forecast horizon increases after the
US state where a firm is headquartered starts to recognize IDD. We
also find that the effect of IDD recognition on management forecasts
is more pronounced for firms that have larger market shares, higher
product market competition, more intensive R&D, shorter distance
to their industry rivals, and more employeeswho possess knowledge
of the firms’ trade secrets.
KEYWORDS
competition, inevitable disclosure doctrine, knowledge economy,
knowledge workers, management forecasts, product market com-
petition, proprietary cost, R&D intensity, trade secrets, voluntary
disclosure
1INTRODUCTION
Information about a firm’s future prospects is valuable, because it can help to reduce information asymmetry in the
capital market and enhance firm valuation (Grossman, 1981; Milgrom, 1981). However,firms are unwilling to reveal
private information about their future profitability as such revelations mayenable their rivals to gauge future industry
demand and adopt operationaland marketing strategies that threaten the disclosing firms’ competitive advantage (e.g.,
Ali, Klasa, & Yeung,2014; Clinch & Verrecchia, 1997; Darrough & Stoughton, 1990; Li, 2010; Verrecchia, 1983, 1990;
Wagenhofer,1990).
While competitors can use the disclosing firm’s forward-looking financial information to envisage how much they
should produce, developing an effective plan to enter the disclosing firm’s product market space would require addi-
tional information, such as operational and marketing strategies,business plans, technical innovations, customer lists,
price lists and/orcost information, that is, information about a firm’s trade secrets. Trade secrets are a firm’s most valu-
able assets (Shapiro & Hassett, 2005) and play a crucial role in maintaining a firm’s competitiveadvantage (e.g., Barney,
1991; Flammer & Ioannou, 2015; Grant, 1996; Helfat et al., 2007; Kogut & Zander,1992; Mahoney & Pandian, 1992;
Png, 2017). Despite the importance of trade secrets for sustaining a firm’s competitive advantage, there has been no
J Bus Fin Acc. 2020;47:397–437. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jbfa c
2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 397
398 LI ANDLI
study examining how trade secret information affects a firm’s incentives to disclose forward-looking financial infor-
mation. In this study, we use the staggered adoption of the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine (IDD)by individual states
in the US to capture firms’ risk of losing trade secrets to rivals and examine the impact of tradesecret information on
firms’ incentives to provide forward-looking financial information, one of the most important types of information for
investors (Beyer,Cohen, Lys, & Walther,2010).
Almeling, Synder,Sapoznikow, McCollum, and Weader (2010) report that more than 75% of the trade secret cases
in US state courts and over 50% of the cases in US federalcourts involve an existing or former employee. The adoption
of the IDD by state courts allows an employer to obtain an injunction prohibiting a former employeefrom working for
a competitor.For example, in the court case of PepsiCo, Inc. vs. V. Redmond, the 7th Circuit ruling states that ‘Plaintiff
PepsiCo, Inc., sought a preliminary injunction against defendants William Redmond and the Quaker Oats Company
to prevent Redmond, a former PepsiCo employee, from divulging PepsiCo tradesecrets and confidential information
in his new job with Quaker and from assuming any duties with Quaker relating to beverage pricing, marketing and
distribution. The district court agreed with PepsiCo and grantedthe injunction. We now affirm that decision’ (PepsiCo,
Inc. v. Redmond, 1995, p. 1263). As adoption of IDD requires a delicate balance between protecting the interest of
employees and that of employers(Friedman, Landes, & Posner, 1991), state courts in the US exhibit different attitudes
in acceptance or rejection of the doctrine (Kahnke,Bundy, & Liebman, 2008). Recent studies show that the adoption of
the IDD significantly reduces employee mobility and knowledge spillovers (Png & Samila, 2015), decreases the risk of
a firm losing its competitive position in its product market (e.g., Klasa, Ortiz-Molina, Serfling, & Srinivasan, 2018; Png,
2017),increases barriers to entry (Gao & Wang, 2018), and enhances firm value (e.g., Castellaneta, Conti, & Kacperczyk,
2017; Klasa et al., 2018; Qiu & Wang, 2018).
We argue that trade secret protection laws can directly and indirectly affect firms’ incentives to provide forward-
looking financial information. First, the adoption of the IDD can reduce the risk that competitors obtain trade secrets
and design effectiveproduction plans or strategies to meet the future industry demand revealed in the disclosing firm’s
forecasts of future profitability, thus lowering the proprietary costs of disclosing forward-looking financial informa-
tion. In particular,in today’s knowledge economy, trade secrets have made products highly differentiated (Crittenden,
Crittenden, & Pierpont, 2015; Hannah, Parent, Pitt, & Berthon, 2014; Reitzig, 2004), and simply knowing the aggre-
gated demand for products is not sufficient for competitors to initiate effective operational plans to gain the market
share of the disclosing firm. For example,in the soft drink market, making information public about the future demand
for soft drinks maynot hurt the disclosing firm’s future profitability if its competitors do not have information about the
firm’s trade secrets on formulas, which are tailored to the tastes of specific consumers (for example,the soft drink for-
mulas for Pepsi vs. Coca Cola). In other words, in order to win the market share of the disclosing firm, competitors will
need both trade secrets and forward-looking financial information to initiate production plans or developentry strate-
gies. The adoption of the IDD better preserves trade secrets within the disclosing firm and therefore makes it more
difficult for rival firms to initiate effective production and/ordevelop strategies.1As a support, Png’s (2017) analytical
model predicts that strengthened trade secret protection laws deter competitors from developingsimilar products or
reverse engineering products that are similar to those protected bytrade secrets.
Second, adoption of the IDD could affect firms’ competitive position indirectly by reducing the agency costs
between shareholders and managers. As IDD adoption could reduce managers’ outside opportunities and managers
are bonded with their firms to a greater extent (Garmaise,2011; Png & Samila, 2015), managers tend to focus on long-
termperformance rather than short-term myopic behavior (Brochet, Loumioti, & Serafeim, 2015) and on strengthening
their firms’ competitive position.2Based on these arguments, we predict that IDD adoption leads to more disclosure of
forward-lookingfinancial information (H1). On the other hand, reduced outside opportunities would potentially induce
1Enhancedtrade secret protection law also reduces a firm’s incentives to reveal proprietary information on their 10Ks filings (Glaeser, 2018; Li, Lin, & Zhang,
2018),further adversely affecting rivals’ ability to gain access to proprietary information and develop operational and marketing strategy effectively.
2We thank the referee for suggesting the possible alternative mechanism through which the IDD affects firms’ competitive position and management
forecasts.
LI ANDLI 399
managerial myopicbehavior, for example, more earnings management to meet or beat short-term earnings targets and
reduction of discretionary spending including R&D and SG&A (Chen, Zhang, & Zhou, 2018). As a result of managerial
myopia, firms would experience poor long-term performance and not be able to maintain their competitive position,
resulting in less frequent management forecasts. Therefore, the effect of the IDD on management forecasts remains
an empirical question.
To empirically test the effect of IDD on management forecasts, we follow Bertrandand Mullainathan (2003) and
Armstrong, Balakrishnan, and Cohen (2012) and apply a difference-in-difference design based on the staggered recog-
nition of the IDD by US state courts. We use the frequency of management earnings forecasts and forecast horizons
to capture firms’ incentives to disclose forward-looking financial information (Ali et al., 2014; Huang, Jennings, & Yu,
2016; Li, 2010). More specifically,we analyze whether recognition of the IDD by state courts increases the frequency
and horizon of management earnings forecasts for firms in these states over the 1998–2011 period.3We find that
recognition of the IDD leads to more frequent management earnings forecasts and forecasts with longer horizons.
These results support the hypothesis that the protection of trade secrets potentially strengthens firms’ competitive
position and reduces the proprietary costs of disclosing forward-looking financial information. Our main results are
also robust to alternative research design including comparing forecasts of firms that located in the states recogniz-
ing the IDD during our sample period with those of firms in neighboring states and examining the timing effect of IDD
recognition on management forecasts.
Clinch and Verrecchia (1997) and Verrecchia (1983, 1990) suggest that information about future profitability is
most useful to competitors when the information is disclosed by firms that produce the most output of an industry,
i.e., when the proprietary content of forward-looking information is higher. If tradesecret protection law reduces the
proprietary costs of disclosing forward-looking financial information, we expect the effect of the IDD on management
forecasts to be stronger among firms with higher market shares (H2). Wefind evidence consistent with this prediction
that the effect of the IDD is significant in firms with market shares in the top 75th percentile of their industry, and is
not significant for firms in the bottom 25th percentile.
Competition affects a firm’s incentives to voluntarily disclose information (Clinch & Verrecchia,1997; Verrecchia,
1983, 1990) and trade secrets are crucially important in maintaining a firm’s competitive position in a product mar-
ket (Eisenhardt & Martin, 2000; Flammer & Ioannou, 2015; Helfat et al., 2007). We predict that IDD recognition has
a greater effect on the proprietary costs of the management forecasts of firms that face greater product market com-
petition (H3) and firms that have more trade secrets (H4). We use the product fluidity index developed byHoberg,
Phillips, and Prabahala (2014) and industry concentrationratio to gauge product market competition. We find that the
effect of IDD recognition on management earnings forecasts is greater when firms face higher product market com-
petition. Using distance to rivals (Klasa et al., 2018) to measure employees’ access to job opportunities of competing
firms, we find that the effect of the IDD is significant only in the subsample of firms with relatively shorter distance
to their rivals; using the intensity of R&D and the proportion of employees possessing trade secrets as proxiesfor the
importance of tradesecrets, we find that IDD recognition leads to more frequent earnings forecasts and earnings fore-
casts with longer horizons in firms with extensiveR&D expenditures and a larger proportion of employees with access
to trade secrets.
Toassess whether the increased management forecast frequency and horizon is due to the impact of the IDD on
managers’ incentives, we analyze the effect of the IDD on management forecasts conditioning on CEO duality, CEO
age and CEO tenure. We do not find conclusive evidence to support that the IDD affects management forecasts by
enhancing interest alignment between CEOs and shareholders. Finally,we find that after IDD recognition, stock trad-
ing liquidity around the announcement of earnings forecasts increases significantly, implying that management fore-
casts become more informative.
3We treat firms headquartered in states that recognized the IDD before 1998 as IDD firms for everyyear in our sample period. This approach follows prior
studieson the staggered adoption of state laws (e.g., Armstrong, Balakrishnan, & Cohen, 2012; Klasa, Ortiz-Molina, Serfling, & Srinivasan, 2018).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT