The effect of firm size, asset ownership, and market prices on regulatory violations

Published date01 October 2019
AuthorGilbert N. Nyaga,Alex Scott
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/joom.1059
Date01 October 2019
RESEARCH ARTICLE
The effect of firm size, asset ownership, and market prices
on regulatory violations
Alex Scott
1
| Gilbert N. Nyaga
2
1
Eli Broad College of Business, Michigan
State University, East Lansing, Michigan
2
D'Amore-McKim School of Business,
Northeastern University, Boston,
Massachusetts
Correspondence
Alex Scott, Eli Broad College of Business,
Michigan State University, 632 Bogue
Street, Office N323, East Lansing, Michigan
48824.
Email: ascott@msu.edu
Handling Editor: John Gray
Abstract
An individual's temptation to violate regulations for personal gain increases with
the economic payoff to do so. Firms, however, adopt strategies to reduce undesir-
able behavior from their employees. This article examines how individuals change
their propensity to violate regulations as the price for their services varies. We posit
that individuals will commit more intentional, but not unintentional, violations as
the payoff to do so increases, and that this effect will be moderated by the size of
the firm for whom he or she works and whether the firm or the individual owns the
assets used for production. To test our hypotheses, we link data from millions of
inspections of truck driver logbooks with spot market prices observed over the same
4-year period. We find that drivers who operate independently intentionally violate
restrictions on their work hours more frequently when prices increaseviolating
34% more frequently when prices are at their highest versus lowestbut larger firms
and the firm's ownership of the assets reduce a driver's responsiveness to price
changes. At the extreme, drivers for large asset-owning firms are completely unre-
sponsive to prices. Asset-owning drivers are responsive to market prices, even for
the largest firms.
KEYWORDS
regulatory compliance, transportation safety
1|INTRODUCTION
Governments regulate firms to ensure safe working conditions
and promote the public welfare (Stigler, 1971). Some regula-
tions raise the cost of inputs, such as imposing a minimum
wage, while others restrict outputs, such as limiting how much
a firm can pollute. Faced with such restrictions, firmsand the
individual decision-makers within a firmare tempted to vio-
late regulations to increase profits (McKendall and Wagner,
1997). Theory suggests that firms balance the costs and bene-
fits of intentionally violating a regulation when deciding
whether to do so (Becker, 1968). Thus, when the payoff to vio-
late increases, ceteris paribus, they should violate more
frequentlya proposition that has found empirical support in
centralized decision-making settings (Harris & Bromiley, 2007;
Wang, Winton, & Yu, 2010). Because noncompliance with a
regulation can negatively affect important outcomes such as
safety (e.g., Brown, Willis, & Prussia, 2000; de Koster, Stam, &
Balk, 2011; Wiengarten, Fan, Lo, & Pagell, 2017) and quality
(Das, Pagell, Behm, & Veltri, 2008), it is important for opera-
tions managers to understand when and where violations are
likely to occur (e.g., Gray, Anand, & Roth, 2015; Staats, Dai,
Hofmann, & Milkman, 2017).
In many cases, the decision to violate does not rest with
central managers but with front-line employees (Pinto,
Leana, & Pil, 2008); examples include mortgage officers
who misrepresent a loanee's financial status (Nguyen &
Pontell, 2010) and vehicle emissions inspectors who pass
Received: 12 April 2018 Revised: 18 July 2019 Accepted: 22 August 2019
DOI: 10.1002/joom.1059
J Oper Manag. 2019;65:685709. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/joom © 2019 Association for Supply Chain Management, Inc. 685
vehicles that should have failed (Gino & Pierce, 2010). In
these situations, the effect of changing payoffs on an individ-
ual's propensity to violate is less clear because, while individ-
uals violate more when payoffs are higher (as shown in
laboratory settings; e.g., Gneezy, 2005, John, Loewenstein, &
Rick, 2014), firms utilize mechanisms such as monitoring
technology (Bendoly, Donohue, & Schultz, 2006; Pierce,
Snow, & McAfee, 2015), payment methods (Pierce &
Snyder, 2008), and terms in the employment contract
(Prendergast, 2015) to reduce undesirable employee behavior.
We examine how an individual's decision to violate var-
ies with changes in the payoff to do so and whether these
decisions are systematically different for employees who
work for small and large firms and based on who owns the
assets used for production. We posit that an individual's pro-
pensity to violate is closely related to their decision-making
autonomy (Jensen & Meckling, 1992), which enables them
to act on opportunities to violate as stipulated in the motive-
opportunity-choice (MOC) framework (McKendall and
Wagner, 1997). An individual's decision to violate (choice)
is influenced by both the potential payoffs from violating
(motive) and the spectrum of decision-making options
(opportunity). This suggests that individuals who operate
their own firms as single-employee, stand-alone entities
(sometimes referred to as the zero agency-cost base case
[Ang, Cole, & Lin, 2000, p. 81]) will violate more fre-
quently as the payoff to do so increases because the individ-
ual has both the opportunitythere are relatively few
restrictions on their decisionsand a stronger motivethey
make more money if they commit the actto violate.
Two organizational factors that could moderate the decisions
of individuals to violate are the size of the firm for whom they
work (Josefy, Kuban, Ireland, & Hitt, 2015) and whether they
own the assets used for production (Grossman & Hart, 1986;
Williamson, 1985). The decisions of individuals who work for
firms of more than one employee affect not only themselves,
but their coworkers; thus, to limit the potential negative exter-
nalities of one employee's bad decisions (e.g., theft, shirking,
unsafe driving), these firms reduce an employee's opportunity
to violate by limiting their potential decisions (Baker & Cullen,
1993). This suggests that employees for larger firms should not
only have a reduced propensity to commit regulatory violations
on average as a first-order effect but also be less responsive to
changing payoffs for violating as a second-order effect.
Firms use asset ownership as a strategy to reduce unwanted
behavior by employees (Prendergast, 2017). Firms who own
the assets (i.e., make) retain more control over how they are
configured and used (Baker & Hubbard, 2003) compared to
firms who contract with others for production purposes
(i.e., buy; Grossman & Hart, 1986; Tsay, Gray, Noh, &
Mahoney, 2018). This suggests that employees who work for
firms that own the assets should have a reduced propensity to
violate regulations on average and be less responsive to chang-
ing payoffs for violating.
We test these ideas in the context of the U.S. trucking
industry, where the Department of Transportation (DOT)
restricts a truck driver's working hours via hours of service
(HOS) regulations to reduce the number of overly-fatigued
drivers on public roads and highways (Cantor, Corsi, &
Grimm, 2006; Miller, 2017). The balance of supply and
demand in the truckload market varies exogenously to an
individual driver's output, thus the marginal value of a driver's
production varies over time and space (Scott, 2018a). We link
data from millions of inspections of truck driver logbooks,
which record their recent work schedules, conducted from
2012 to 2015 spatially and temporally with prices observed in
private auctions for spot truckload services.
We find that intentional violations, such as exceeding
legal driving limits, occur more frequently when the prices
for a driver's services are relatively high, but not uni-
ntentional violations, such as paperwork errors. Drivers who
own and operate their own single-employee firms are highly
responsive to market pricesthey increase their frequency
of intentional violations by 13.1% per unit increase in spot
pricesbut, at the other extreme, drivers who operate a
large firm's trucks are not. In general, drivers who own their
trucks are considerably more likely to violate, both on aver-
age and in their responsiveness to market prices, compared
to drivers who use the firm's trucks, and this effect holds for
even the largest firms.
We make several contributions in this research. Much
research examines the factors that contribute to dishonest behav-
ior
1
for example, the probability of detection (Fischbacher &
Föllmi-Heusi, 2013), pay relative to others (John et al., 2014),
altruism (Erat & Gneezy, 2012), and fatigue (Mead, Baumeister,
Gino, Schweitzer, & Ariely, 2009)and a central result of this
research stream is that people are more dishonest when the payoff
to do so is larger (Balasubramanian, Bennett, & Pierce, 2017;
Duggan & Levitt, 2002; Gneezy, 2005; Jacob & Levitt, 2003).
Much less research, however, examines how payoffs affect dis-
honest behavior by individuals in organizations (Leana &
Meuris, 2015) as opposed to the more common laboratory set-
ting, and what factors may moderate the propensity for dishonest
behavior.
We also contribute to the study of compliance with regu-
lations and processes (e.g., Anand, Gray, & Siemsen, 2012;
Ko, Mendeloff, & Gray, 2010; Staats et al., 2017). Our study
highlights how two common and important organizational
factorsfirm size and asset ownershipinteract with pay-
offs to affect an individual's compliance. Our unique and
rich dataset combines price variation with violations found
in roadside inspections, which allows us to credibly evaluate
changes in compliance behavior with changes in the price
for services.
686 SCOTT AND NYAGA

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT