The effect of ad blocking on website traffic and quality

AuthorJoel Waldfogel,Johnny Ryan,Benjamin Shiller
Published date01 March 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12218
Date01 March 2018
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.49, No. 1, Spring 2018
pp. 43–63
The effect of ad blocking on website traffic
and quality
Benjamin Shiller
Joel Waldfogel∗∗
and
Johnny Ryan∗∗∗
Ad blockingsoftware allows Internet users to obtain information without generatingad revenue for
site owners, potentially undermining investmentsin content. We explore the impact of site-level ad
blocker usage on website quality, as inferred fromtraffic. We find that each additional percentage
point of site visitors blocking ads reduces its traffic by 0.67% over 35 months. Impacted sites
provide less content over time, providing corroboration for the mechanism. Effects on revenue
are compounded; ad blocking reducesvisits, and remaining visitors blocking ads do not generate
revenue. We conclude that ad blocking poses a threat to the ad-supported web.
1. Introduction
Intellectual property is, in general, protected by a combination of law and technology that
may together allow sellers to appropriate enough of consumers’ willingness to pay to finance
the creation of new products. The development of various digital technologies over the past few
decades has undermined sellers’ ability to appropriate consumers’ willingness to pay, raising the
possibility of a diminished supply of new information and entertainment products. For example,
new digital technologies have challenged traditional revenue models through direct piracy (e.g.,
Napster), diversion of attention to aggregators rather than the underlying information sources
(e.g., Google News), and pure-playadvertising platfor ms such as Craigslist, whichdivert revenue
Brandeis University; shiller@brandeis.edu.
∗∗University of Minnesota and NBER; jwaldfog@umn.edu.
∗∗∗PageFair; johnny@pagefair.com.
Wethank two anonymous referees and the Editor for very useful suggestions, and colleagues at Harvard Business School’s
Digital Initiative for lively discussions. We also would like to thank our discussants, Ana Gazmuri, Josh Gans, Bradley
Shapiro, and Ken Wilbur,for constr uctivesuggestions. Last, we would like to thank participants for helpful suggestions
at numerous seminars [Brandeis University (2016), Carlson School of Management (2016), The FCC (2016), Harvard
Business School (2016), MIT (2016), and NBER Productivity Seminar (2017)], and Conferences [IIOC (2017), NBER
Economics of Digitization (2017), Toulouses IDEI-TSE-IAST (2017), and ZEW ICT (2017)].
C2018, The RAND Corporation. 43
44 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
from newspaper classified ads (Rob and Waldfogel, 2006; Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf, 2007;
Seamans and Zhu, 2014).1
Despite these and related challenges, much of the commercial information on the web is
provided under ad-financed business models. Although a growingnumber of newspaper sites have
moved behind paywalls (Chiou and Tucker, 2013), most other commercial information sources
rely on advertising. The finance of information production with ad revenue has come under
threat with the development of ad blocking technologies. Ad blockers, such as Adblock Plus,
are browser extensions that allow users to browse the web without having to see sites’ ads. As a
result, many site visitors obtain information without seeing ads, clicking through to advertisers’
sites, or otherwise generating revenue for site owners. The use of ad blockers has grown sharply
in recent years. By some estimates, roughly a quarter of site visitors used ad blockers by 2016, a
magnitude of ad blocking that may produce a serious threat to site revenue and, if revenue losses
undermine investment, a possible threat to consumers’ access to appealing content.2This is the
question this article seeks to explore.
Weare not the first to consider this problem. Anderson and Gans (2011) develop a theoretical
model of the impact of ad-avoidance technologieson content markets that is useful for guiding our
analysis. Bergemann and Bonatti (2011) and Johnson and Myatt (2006) also use similar models.
Adapting their setup to this context, users choose whether to incur the one-time cost of adopting
an ad blocker, balancing the cost of adoption against their distaste for ads. Ad-intolerant users are
more likely to adopt, with two consequences.3First, ad blocker usage by a site’s visitors reduces
the site’s revenue if at least some of those users would have visited the site in the absence of
ad blocking. The relevant mechanism, as in the traditional literature on the relationship between
intellectual property revenue appropriation and supply, is that reduced revenue may undermine
a site’s ability to invest, which could manifest itself as a diminished site that is less appealing to
potential visitors. Webusers then visit the degraded site less, reducing the site’s traffic. Second,in
the presence of ad blocking, a site’s remaining revenue-generating visitors are less ad-intolerant,
leading the site to run more ads, increasing the nuisance cost of visiting the site.
Studying these mechanisms empirically requires data on site trafficand site-specific measures
of ad blocker usage. This is challenging, but wehave obtained unique, proprietary, and site-specific
data on the share of site visitors using ad blockers at a few thousand sites, matched with Alexa
traffic data. These data allow us to explore the impact of ad blocker usage on site trafficbetween
2013 and 2016. We also explore the mechanism linking ad blocking with traffic using data, from
the Internet Archive, on the number of ads at these sites, as well as the amount of content (i.e.,
number of words), at the beginning and end of the sample period.
Aggregate ad blocking has grown rapidly between 2013 and 2016. During this period, we
find that sites with a high proportion of ad blocking visitors experience deterioration in their traffic
ranks, relative to sites with fewer ad blocking visitors. In our main analyses, we find—using a
conservative approach—that each additional percentage point of site visitors using ad blockers
raises (worsens) a site’s traffic rank by about 0.6% over a 35-month period. We have two ways
of dealing with possible concerns about unobserved heterogeneity. First, in contrast to our basic
result—worsening ranks at sites whose users block ads—those same sites did not experience
worsening ranks prior to the widespread use of ad blocking. Second, instrumental variables
based on the geographic proximity of sites’ users to the source of the dominant ad blocking
software (Germany) deliver consistent, albeit weaker, results. Data on site content supports our
interpretation; sites experiencing greater ad blocking decrease their word counts over time.
1Several historical examples exist of technology that allowsconsumption without compensation to rights holders,
including TiVo and Aereo.
2www.emarketer.com/Article/US-Ad-Blocking-Jump-by-Double-Digits-This-Year/1014111.
3Anderson and Gans (2011) also outline conditions for an equilibrium with the complete unravelling of the ad-
supported content market. Our exercise explorestwo of their major predictions. Our main question is whether the growing
adoption of ad blocking technology undermines content investment.
C
The RAND Corporation 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT