The Dynamics of Interest Representation at the U.S. Supreme Court

AuthorThomas Hansford
Published date01 December 2011
Date01 December 2011
DOI10.1177/1065912910395325
Political Research Quarterly
64(4) 749 –764
© 2011 University of Utah
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/1065912910395325
http://prq.sagepub.com
How do interests respond to their opponents’ lobbying
activities in a policy venue? Do they seek to directly con-
front and counter the advocacy efforts of the opposition,
or do they allocate their resources to advocacy efforts tar-
geting institutions in which opposing interests are not as
active? Assuming that organized interests exert some
influence over policy outcomes or at least provide rele-
vant information to policy makers, the degree to which
opposing interests compete in a given policy venue or
instead sort themselves into relatively noncompetitive
venues has significant implications for whether policy
outputs will exhibit representational or informational
bias.
Despite the significance of these questions for the
study of American politics, policy making, and represen-
tation, social scientists have not yet fully settled on the
answers. According to the pluralist paradigm, American
politics is fundamentally about the competition between
opposing interests (e.g., Becker 1983; Truman 1951).
This perspective generally suggests that interests will be
responsive to the lobbying activities of their opponents.
This responsiveness could result from either policy-seek-
ing or resource-maximizing behavior. To the extent that
interests pursue influence over policy, they may want to
provide policy makers with information that offsets the
information provided by opponents (Austen-Smith and
Wright 1994). Organizational maintenance concerns may
also cause interest groups to seek out conflictual venues
in which a strong opposition is present, as this may make
it easier to offer purposive incentives to potential
supporters.
Empirical studies of the responsiveness of organized
interests to the lobbying activities of opposing interests
provide mixed results, however. Holyoke (2003) and
Nownes (2000) present survey-based evidence that orga-
nized interests are more likely to lobby policy venues in
which opposing interests are active, while W. L. Hansen
and Mitchell (2000) find that corporate political activity
increases in response to the advocacy efforts of unions.
Austen-Smith and Wright (1994) examine lobbying
activities in the U.S. Senate and also find evidence of
what they call counteractive lobbying (but see
Baumgartner and Leech 1996). In the context of the pol-
icy venue to be examined here, the U.S. Supreme Court,
Solowiej and Collins (2009) demonstrate that the filing of
amicus curiae briefs in support of a litigant corresponds
with the filing of amicus curiae briefs in support of the
opposing litigant. Other studies, however, find little to no
1University of California, Merced, Merced, CA, USA
Corresponding Author:
Thomas Hansford, University of California, Merced, PO Box 2039,
Merced, CA 95344
Email: thansford@ucmerced.edu
The Dynamics of Interest
Representation at the U.S. Supreme Court
Thomas Hansford1
Abstract
How do organized interests respond to their opponents’ advocacy activities in a policy venue? Utilizing data on amicus
curiae filings at the U.S. Supreme Court, the author estimates vector error correction and vector autoregression
models that allow him test whether interests respond, in a dynamic sense, to the efforts of the “other side.” The
author capitalizes on the temporal sequencing of variation in advocacy activity to gain leverage on the causal connection
between the behaviors of opposing sets of interests and provides a richer portrait of the dynamics of interest
representation in a policy venue. The results reveal that organized interests respond positively to the advocacy
activities of their opponents by exhibiting both short-term counteraction and long-term countermobilization, implying
that over the long run, interest representation at the Court is responsive and perhaps balanced.
Keywords
law, courts, political organizations, parties
750 Political Research Quarterly 64(4)
evidence of organized interests responding to activities of
their opponents (e.g., Ando 2003; Hojnacki and Kimball
1998; Lowery et al. 2005; McKay and Yackee 2007). The
mixed results generated by this literature may be the
result of differing assumptions about the timing of orga-
nized interest responses to their opposition, the static
nature of the analyses, and accompanying difficulties in
identifying causal connections in the data.
In an effort to better understand how organized inter-
ests respond to the advocacy efforts of their opponents, I
examine the dynamics of organized interest involvement
as amicus curiae at the U.S. Supreme Court and assess the
presence of both short-term and long-term responses to
the filing of briefs by the opposition. The Court is an
attractive venue for studying organized interest counter-
action and countermobilization because lobbying efforts
in the form of amicus curiae briefs are public record and
can be observed far back in time. To properly assess the
dynamics of organized interest activity it is critical to
have a valid and reliable measure of advocacy activity
over a meaningful time span.
Prior work examining the involvement of organized
interests at the Supreme Court reveals that a wide variety
of interests file amicus curiae briefs at the Court (Caldeira
and Wright 1990) and that the fundamental compatibility
between institutional features of the judiciary and the
nature of an interest group affects the likelihood of the
group using the courts (Scheppele and Walker 1991).
There is also evidence that the decision to file an amicus
brief is a function of the receptiveness of the Court
(Kobylka 1991), the Court’s need for information
(Hansford 2004a), and the potential for this form of advo-
cacy to allow membership-based groups to attract support
(Hansford 2004b). This line of work has not, however,
directly addressed whether interests respond to their
opponents in a dynamic fashion.
Using data on amicus curiae filings from the 1946 to
2006 terms of the Supreme Court, I estimate vector error
correction (VEC) and vector autoregression (VAR) mod-
els that allow a test of whether advocacy efforts respond,
in a dynamic sense, to the efforts of the “other side.” This
modeling strategy provides a better test of the causal con-
nections between the activities of opposing sets of orga-
nized interests because of the focus on the temporal
sequencing of variation in amicus activity. These dynamic
analyses illuminate the extent to which organized interest
advocacy efforts are responsive to shocks in the level of
activity of opposing interests. Existing research typically
assesses lobbying activity occurring at one point in time,
which makes it difficult to rule out spurious relationships
and pin down causal connections.
The results of the model estimations (using both
pooled and issue-specific data) reveal that organized
interests respond to the advocacy activities of their
opponents in both the short and long term. An increase in
the number of amicus briefs filed on one side leads to an
increase in briefs filed by the other side, in the immedi-
ately following and subsequent Court terms. These results
provide evidence that organized interests exhibit both
short-term counteraction and long-term responsiveness,
consistent with countermobilization, in the face of activ-
ity from their opponents. Consistent with pluralism, inter-
est representation at the Court appears responsive and
perhaps balanced in the long term. It is possible, though,
that institutional characteristics of the judiciary promote
counteraction and countermobilization on the part of
involved interests. Ironically, this would suggest a par-
ticularly democratic, in the pluralistic sense, role for the
Court.
How Do Interests Respond to
the Lobbying Activities of Their
Opponents?
Assume that there are interests, in the most general sense,
on both sides of an issue. How do interests on one side
(to be labeled A, for ease of discussion), which may be
organized and active or may be latent, respond to the
advocacy activities of the other side (B)? More specifi-
cally, how does A respond to the lobbying efforts of B in
a particular venue? The pluralist paradigm views
American politics as centering on the competition
between opposing interests (e.g., Becker 1983; Truman
1951). This active competition over policy outcomes
leads organized interests to be responsive to the lobbying
activities of their opponents. While Olson’s (1965)
famous critique of the assumption that latent interests
will necessarily organize in response to threats took some
of the wind out of the pluralist’s sails, recent work pro-
vides pluralistic, or perhaps neo-pluralistic, theoretical
justifications for the expectation that interests will
respond to the advocacy efforts of their opponents.
Specifically, there are both policy- and organizational-
maintenance-based arguments for the possibility that
organized interests will respond to an increase in the lob-
bying by opponents by increasing their own advocacy
efforts in the same venue. Below, I outline these argu-
ments and indicate how they apply to interest activity at
the Supreme Court.
Policy Motivations and Information
Provision
Dating back to Milbrath (1963), scholars have equated
lobbying with an attempt to influence policy outcomes
through the strategic provision of information to policy
makers. This should be particularly true of the lobbying

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT