The DNA of Enterprise: Jane Jacobs and Henry George on Innovation and Development Through Spin‐Offs

Date01 May 2015
Published date01 May 2015
AuthorDavid Ellerman
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12104
The DNA of Enterprise: Jane Jacobs and
Henry George on Innovation and
Development Through Spin-Offs
By DAVID ELLERMAN*
ABSTRACT. The main training grounds for entrepreneurial, technical,
and business capacities are existing businesses. There are two ways
that this training can lead to new growth—just as there are two ways
that existing biological DNA can lead to the growth of bio-mass,
namely, (1) existing organisms getting bigger or (2) by spinning out
offspring who in turn can spin out more offspring. Where growth has
been vibrant, e.g., Silicon Valley, it has followed the second route,
growth by offspring. This is also the biological principle of plenitude.
Conventional ownership structures lessen the incentives for spin-offs
since managers do not wantto reduce the “empire” under their control.
The biological principle of plenitude is best implemented with
employee-owned or cooperative firms (e.g., as in the Mondragon
cooperative group). Inspired by ideas first proposed by Henry George
and Jane Jacobs, this article explores the social benefits of applying the
biological principle of plenitude by encouraging the proliferation of
enterprises. Thisposes a conundrum for societies organized around the
private business model: How can the social benefits of spin-offs be
realized when managers do not have an incentive to foster new
businesses? We conclude with ways to address this problem.
Introduction: The Social Roots of Business Innovation
Nature abhors a vacuum, and economic development is no exception.
Nothing comes from nothing. New businesses build on old businesses,
and new ideas derive from old ones. The central question of economic
development should therefore be: How can we create the conditions
under which a city and a region form a vast learning network, in which
*University of California at Riverside, 4044 Mt. Vernon Ave., Riverside, CA 92507
USA. david@ellerman.org. www.ellerman.org
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 74, No. 3 (May, 2015).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12104
V
C2015 The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
ideas and personnel from one business can influence the development
of new enterprises in an ongoing process that intensifies the network
and makes it more productive?
Standard microeconomic theory, as represented in college textbooks,
provides no clues about this process or about the true nature of enter-
prises. Micro theory treats each business as a unit that transforms labor
and raw materials into a finished product or service and then sells it.
There is no basis for seeing in that description how the behavior of
businesses enables an economy to grow. Yet growth does occur, and it
arises from humble beginnings that can be discovered by paying close
attention to how businesses function, interact, and split off new units in
processes that are verysimilar to biological ones.
Two thinkers, Henry George and Jane Jacobs, separated by almost a
century, offered ways of thinking about business enterprises that relied
on organic metaphors that are quite at odds with the mechanistic meta-
phors normally encountered in economics texts. To see how their ideas
relate to modern business and theprocess of innovation, let us turn first
to the question of how firms both replicate themselves and transform
themselves in response to changing conditions.
Internal Knowledge: External Benefits
Every company has two outputs: its product and itself. By “itself” is
meant the company as an organization of people trained in the systems
necessary to run the business and in the technologies necessary to pro-
duce the products or services of the company. While some skills are
already possessed by people when they join the organization, the com-
pany still has to have the training capacity to specialize those skills to
the systems and technologies specific to the firm. In addition, as people
leave or retire, the company has to recreate those human capabilities
within the firm.
While the company’s ordinary products may be protected by patents
and trademarks, there is generally no such exclusive rights over the
human capabilities developed in the company. When those capabilities
leave the company, then it is a positive externality—a benefit to society
not counted as such in any accounts. In A. C. Pigou’s ([1920] 1932: 204)
classic book on normative economics, he noted that the businesses in a
The American Journal of Economics and Sociology532

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT