The Dilemma of International Diversification: Evidence from the European Sovereign Debt Crisis

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajfs.12293
Published date01 April 2020
Date01 April 2020
The Dilemma of International
Diversification: Evidence from the European
Sovereign Debt Crisis*
Bill B. Francis**
Lally School of Management, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, United States
Iftekhar Hasan
Fordham University, United States
Bank of Finland, Finland and University of Sydney, Australia
Gergana L. Kostova
AIG Group, United States
Sami Ben Naceur
International Monetary Fund, United States
Received 31 July 2019; Received in current form (1
st
revision) 27 January 2020; Accepted 1 February 2020
Abstract
This paper tests how capital markets value the international diversification of banks in good
and in bad economic times by investigating changes in domestic and foreign sovereign debt
ratings before and during the European sovereign debt crisis. Tracing 320 European banks in
29 countries and 226 credit rating announcements for European sovereigns between 1 Jan-
uary 2001 and 15 August 2012, we show that the market values banks with access to foreign
funds. Despite occasional adverse effects immediately following negative news regarding
sovereign credit rating changes, international diversification was found to be beneficial to
European banks, especially during periods of distress.
Keywords International diversification; Banks; Sovereign debt crisis; Europe
JEL Classification: F23, F61, G01, G14, G15, G21
1. Introduction
Crises can be difficult or even impossible to predict, especially when they concern
developed, economically stable countries. Therefore, banks can benefit significantly
*The authors are thankful to an anonymous reviewer, the editors (L. K. Ng and K. Park), R.
Alsakka, and O. A. Gwilym for helpful comments and guidance. The usual caveats apply.
**Corresponding author: Lally School of Management, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy,
NY 12180, United States. Tel: +1-518-276-3908, email: francb@rpi.edu.
Asia-Pacific Journal of Financial Studies (2020) 49, 299–346 doi:10.1111/ajfs.12293
©2020 Korean Securities Association 299
from pursuing strategies that can help keep them afloat in critical situations such as
the recent European sovereign debt crisis. In this paper, we find that the market
valued the international diversification of banks positively during the most critical
periods of the crisis. More specifically, geographic diversification, income diversifi-
cation, and maintaining a United States cross-listing were all shown to be beneficial
to banks when their home sovereigns as well as foreign sovereigns in which they
maintained subsidiaries failed to sustain their financial and economic stability.
Backed by these findings, we discuss some strategies to alleviate banks’ losses in
times of great distress.
In late 2008, it became apparent that several major European Union (EU) and
EU Community countries including Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain
(often referred to as GIIPS or PIIGS, henceforth GIIPS), among others would be
unable to repay or refinance their sovereign debts. Anticipating the outcom e of this
crisis, the EU took various measures to prevent a potential sovereign debt default.
1
Despite all efforts, however, many euro area countries’ sovereign debt ratings were
downgraded, indicating an increased likelihood of default.
The literature shows that a potential sovereign debt default can result in numer-
ous costs for that country, including reputational costs, international trade exclu-
sion costs, political costs to the country’s authorities (Borensztein and Panizza
2009), and so on. Most importantly, the banking system suffers significantly
2
due to
increased cost and reduced availability of funding. This results in banks choosing or
being forced to lend less money (de Haas and van Lelyveld 2006; Popov and Van
Horen 2015; Deli and Hasan 2017),
3
and thus, the country’s economy shrinks
(Ongena et al. 2015; Abbassi et al. 2016; Behn et al. 2016; Bremus and Neugebauer
2018). It becomes more difficult for governments to service their debt through tax
revenues, consequently increasing the risk of a sovereign debt default and bringi ng
the country back to the beginning of this vicious cycle (Acharya et al. 2014). Fur-
thermore, the banking sector’s requirement for interconnectedness within and
1
For instance, in May 2010, the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and the European
Financial Stability Mechanism (EFSM) were created in order to safeguard financial stability in
the EU by providing temporary financial assistance to EU member states in need, issuing several
stimulus packages in order to avoid potential sovereign debt defaults. In addition to the EFSF
and EFSM, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) has also provided financial help to EU
Member States. Table A1 in Appendix A summarizes rescue package details and their announce-
ment dates, as well as the dates when the decisions to create the EFSF and the EFSM were taken.
2
See Committee on the Global Financial System (2011) for a detailed discussion of the effects
of the sovereign debt crisis on banks.
3
Popov and Van Horen (2015) show that during the financial crisis, European banks exposed
to GIIPS sovereign debt significantly reduced syndicated lending especially to foreign borrow-
ers other than the US, increasing their home bias.
B. B. Francis et al.
300 ©2020 Korean Securities Association
between countries can facilitate spillovers, especially if the affected country is part
of an economic or monetary union (like the EU or the euro area).
There are four main transmission channels through which sovereign risk affects
bank funding (Committee on the Global Financial System, henceforth CGFS 2011).
The most obvious is through a bank’s holding of government debt, which is directly
reflected on the bank’s balance sheet. The European Banking Authority’s 2010 bank
stress test
4
shows that while banks domiciled within the euro area are mostly
exposed to their home sovereigns’ debts (Acharya and Steffen 2015; Bremus and
Fratzscher 2015; Cassol and Koulischer 2019), they are also exposed to foreign
sovereigns’ debt (Blundell-Wignall and Slovik 2010; Bolton and Jeanne 2011). Sec-
ond, as sovereign risk increases, the value of a bank’s collateral decreases, likewise
decreasing the bank’s access to wholesale funding.
5
Third, sovereign ratings often
act as ceilings for all domestic issuers of debt (including banks),
6
which further lim-
its the home banks’ funding choices. In addition to this, institutional investors,
who are only allowed to hold investment-grade bonds, may be forced to liquidate
their bank bond holdings if their ratings fall below the investment level.
7
Lastly,
increased sovereign risk reduces the benefits that banks can receive from implicit
and explicit government guarantees.
8
4
See http://www.eba.europa.eu/EU-wide-stress-testing/2011/2011-EU-wide-stress-test-results.a
spx for further details.
5
See Bolton and Jeanne (2011) for a more detailed discussion of the spillover effect from
sovereign debt crises to banks through the collateral transmission channel under financial
and fiscal integration.
6
This means that the credit ratings of all issuers within a country may not exceed the sover-
eign one. This rule is particularly problematic in times of distress, as it may further exacer-
bate the economic situation in the country. Williams et al. (2013) show that sovereign rating
changes in emerging markets are often followed by bank rating changes in the same direc-
tion, although the strength of this relationship is dependent on certain characteristics of the
country and bank in question.
7
Bonds with ratings lower than BBB-/Baa are considered speculative-grade.
8
Explicit and implicit government bank funding guarantees aim to reduce the costs of and
improve access to funding for banks. Explicit guarantees are formal agreements that a govern-
ment will prevent the potential default of a bank on its bonds, while implicit guarantees refer
to the market’s expectations that a government will prevent a bank from defaulting on its
bonds. It is most relevant for banks that are essential for the economy, following the “too big
to fail” logic. The value of explicit guarantees is measured as the difference in the yields of a
bank’s government-guaranteed and non-government-guaranteed senior bond. The value of
an implicit guarantee is measured as the difference between a bank’s “issuer rating” (which
takes into account the likelihood of government or other support in case of a bank’s poten-
tial default) and its “standalone rating” (which only takes into account the bank’s own cred-
itworthiness, disregarding the likelihood of any external intervention in case of a bank’s
default) (CGFS, 2011). Alternatively, Abbassi et al. (2016) proxy implicit guarantees with a
bank ownership dummy.
Internationalization and Debt Crisis
©2020 Korean Securities Association 301

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT