The development trinity: How regional integration impacts growth, inequality and poverty

Date01 July 2019
Published date01 July 2019
AuthorAlisa DiCaprio,Amelia U. Santos‐Paulino,Maria V. Sokolova
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12788
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The development trinity: How regional integration
impacts growth, inequality and poverty
Amelia U. Santos-Paulino
1
|
Alisa DiCaprio
2
|
Maria V. Sokolova
3
1
Division for Africa, Least Developed Countries and Special Programmes, Geneva, Switzerland
2
R3, New York City, New York, USA
3
Division on International Trade and Commodities, UNCTAD, Geneva, Switzerland
KEYWORDS
free trade agreements, growth, inequality, least developed countries, low-income countries, panel data, poverty, regional
integration
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Regional trade agreements (RTAs) can be a useful tool to promote growth and development.
1
They structure trade in a way that can increase domestic productive capacity, promote upward
harmonisation of standards, improve institutional quality, introduce technical knowhow and
increase preferential access to desirable markets. These are outcomes that could benefit develop-
ing economies in general and particularly least developed and lowincome countries.
However, most studies of RTAs show that, on average, less developed countries benefit less
(see, e.g., Ariyasajjakorn, Gander, Ratanakomut, & Reynolds, 2009; Feenstra, 1996). Also, while
RTAs can lead to convergence, some research shows that the poorer countries in a regio n are more
likely to diverge (e.g., Venables, 1999).
Moreover, noneconomic impacts of trade agreements may also be problematic for developing
countries. While RTAs have the potential to promote higher standards for labour, environment, trans-
parency and other progressive reforms and noneconomic policy objectives; this comes with concerns
about policy sovereignty and the balance between commitments and flexibility. And RTAs may erode
nonreciprocal preference schemes such as the Generalised System of Preferences or special and differ-
ential treatment for LDCs, without providing affected countries with the opportunity to find solutions.
2
Despite this uneven distribution of benefits, most developing countries are members of at least
one RTA.
3
Policymakers view RTAs as the de facto way to access the global trade regime.
[Correction added on 8 May 2019 after first online publication: The Acknowledgement section was previously omitted and
has been added in this version.]
1
Regional trade agreements are defined as any agreement involving tariffs lower than mostfavoured nation rates.
2
See Bagwell and Staiger (2001) for a related discussion about national policies in the context of international economic
institutions.
3
Fortyeight countries are currently designated by the United Nations as least developed countries(LDCs), entitling them
to aid, preferential market access and special technical assistance, among other concessions. The regional distribution of
LDCs is as follows: 34 in Africa, 9 in Asia, 4 in the Pacific and 1 in the Caribbean.
Received: 28 February 2018
|
Revised: 18 January 2019
|
Accepted: 22 January 2019
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12788
World Econ. 2019;42:19611993. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec © 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
1961
However, the reality is that most RTAs are SouthSouth agreements,
4
which are often
poorly implemented and are unlikely to help members ramp up their participation in the global
trading system.
The literature is controversial on the benefits of regionalisation and their de facto dist ribution.
Thus, this paper aims at empirically investigating the impact of regionalisation on key development
outcomes, for different development clusters. In particular, we explore the hypothesis that regional-
isation has a nonlinear impact on economic growth, inequality and poverty for developing coun-
tries. We explore this question on both national and regional levels.
The key contribution of the paper is the introduction two measures of regional integration,
which simplify the complicated impacts of regionalism into easily measurable and descriptive
indices. The first measure defines regionalisation as a sovereign country trade policy tool by using
bilateral trade linkages among states. The second measure gauges the weighted regionalisation of
trading partners, which captures the extent to which a country is engaged in the regional networks
of other countries. This regional dimension of analysis has received scant attention in the literature,
despite the evidence of bowlsand netsof trade agreements which imply a domino effect when
one country enters into a trade agreement.
Our results show that both a country's own regionalisation and its exposure to the regionalisa-
tion of others positively contribute to economic growth globally. However, the findings vary by
regional clustering, with some areas such as subSaharan Africa having experienced relatively
lower growth as a result of internal regionalisation and exposure to external regionalisation. In
addition, economic growth results in positive distributional outcomes in the developing country
clusters that are involved in more regionalisation, compared with the rest of the world. Overall, we
observe that location in a region that is characterised by more frequent RTA participation has
higher growth, a smaller increase in inequality and a reduction in poverty when regionali sation
increases among the participants.
5
Section 2 addresses these conclusions in light of the exiting lit-
erature. Section 3 then presents our empirical approach to measuring the impact of regional inte-
gration on development and describes the data. Section 4 presents the results of the empirical
estimations. Section 5 concludes.
2
|
LITERATURE REVIEW
In Viner's time, RTAs were about trade liberalisation. As a result, much of the early literature
focused on the trade outcomes of tariff reductions. This early literature informs our hypothesis that
the RTAs will impact both members and nonmembers. Unlike much of the existing trade litera-
ture, our analysis pulls together four very different subliteratures in the trade space. These areas
have developed separately in part due to the multidirectional impacts of trade. In this section, we
weave these together to illustrate how our analysis expands, questions and disputes earli er
findings.
Both our empirical strategy and our premise that changes in trade are impacted by both mem-
bers and nonmembers are rooted in the trade and growth literature. This recognised early on that
both members and nonmembers of trade agreements are impacted by their implementation. Early
contributions include Viner (1950), Lipsey (1960), Corden (1972) among others. Based on Viner's
4
See Figure A1 in the Appendix.
5
Baldwin (2006) referred to the wellknown puzzle of overlapping RTAs described by Bhagwati (1991) as spaghetti bowl
to describe the proliferation of trade agreements in Asia.
1962
|
SANTOSPAULINO ET AL.
twogoods model, the main effects of a custom union are threefold: first a production effect, that is
trade creation and trade diversion; second, consumption effects; and, third terms of trade changes
with the rest of the world. Corden (1972) incorporates economies of scale into customs union the-
ory, incorporating costreduction and tradesuppression impacts to the standard Vinerian concepts.
And, Corden (1974) proposes a theory of domestic divergences which provides a rationale for gov-
ernment intervention to increase welfare by offsetting the effects of distorting policies or of market
imperfections. Other, more complex taxonomies propose further effects working through import
and export diversion, and importexport substitution within members. Some authors, for example,
Rodrik (2018), argue that looking only at trade creation and diversion is an insufficient way to
evaluate RTAs.
From here, our work delves more deeply into the question of how different patterns of engage-
ment impact domestic welfare outcomes. This diverges from the empirical trade and growth litera-
ture which has attempted to analyse the effects of FTAs in terms of trade creation and trade
diversion (see, e.g., Baier & Bergstrand, 2007).
6
Magee (2008) controls for exportersand impor-
tersfixed effects along other vectors of unobserved characteristics between countr y pairs, to over-
come the structural problems of standard gravity models. According to his paper, aggregate shocks
to a country's imports can be large relative to the effects of a regional trade agreement; thus, it is
challenging to determine a counterfactual level of trade that would have occurred in the absence of
the agreement, and hence, the trade diversion effect is not evident. The findings also point out that
the effects of an agreement can vary considerably across countries within a trade block, and the
impact of the trade preferences can change over time. Dai, Yotov, and Zylkin (2014) find that
FTAs divert FTA member imports away from nonmember countries. Furthermore, FTAs lead to a
largerstill decrease in internal tradethat is, domestic saleswithin member countries. The diver -
sion of internal trade intensifies with the number of FTAs a given country pair.
Our focus on the lowerincome members of RTAs and the domestic gains that are possible
through their international agreements takes its inspiration from the recent literature, which has
suggested that regional agreements may be beneficial or harmful depending on the particular coun-
tries involved, and the extent of trade creation relative to trade diversion (Panagariya, 2000).
7
Importantly, the net impact of a regional trade agreement for its members will depend on their ini-
tial economic structure and parameter values, and such is essentially an empirical issue that must
be determined by data analysis (Burfisher, Sherman Robinson, & Thierfelder, 2001).
Our empirical strategy uses two estimation techniques from previous studies on changes in
trade patterns. First, expost studies examine trade flows after the RTA has been implemented and
compare the actual levels of trade with a prediction of trade in the absence of the RTA. Second,
exante studies use trade patterns and estimated elasticities or computable general equilibrium mod-
els prior to the agreement to calculate the predicted impact of eliminating trade barriers with a
partner country. However, as both approaches are subject to criticism (Magee, 2008), we use panel
data analysis to look at the short and longterm impacts of our novel measures of regional integra-
tion and the development trinity of growth, inequality and poverty.
Our measurement of nonmember country effects is directly in line with existing studies. One
difference is that existing work has focused largely on trade outcomes such as price effects and
terms of trade impacts (see, e.g., Winters & Chang, 2002) as well as the effects on economic
6
Gravity models have been subject to extensive criticism. However, the review of such models is beyond the scope of this
paper. Anderson (2011) provides an extensive review of the gravity models of international trade.
7
Panagariya (2000) provides an extensive survey of the topic.
SANTOSPAULINO ET AL.
|
1963

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT