The determinants of international migration: Unbundling the role of economic, political and social institutions

Published date01 June 2020
AuthorImran Arif
Date01 June 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12889
World Econ. 2020;43:1699–1729. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec
|
1699
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 30 November 2018
|
Revised: 16 August 2019
|
Accepted: 1 October 2019
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12889
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The determinants of international migration:
Unbundling the role of economic, political and social
institutions
ImranArif
Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC, USA
KEYWORDS
culture, democracy, freedom, gravity model, migration
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Potential migrants may decide to leave their origin country for a variety of reasons including eco-
nomic, political, demographic and social conditions in the origin and destination countries. They may
decide to migrate if these conditions improve in the destination country—pull factors—or if these
conditions deteriorate in the origin country—push factors. Potential migrants compare economic,
psychological and emotional benefits and costs of migration1; they decide to migrate whenever their
private economic and non-monetary benefits exceed costs. If policymakers understand what motivates
migration, they can make suitable policies to encourage brain gain and discourage brain drain.
Economic researchers have been identifying economic and non-economic factors motivating inter-
national migration; helping policymakers to understand the implications of migration; and helping
them to make domestic policies that would have a direct or indirect effect on migration. Some re-
searchers have found the role of socioeconomic and political factors of migration.2 For example,
Uebelmesser, Geis, and Werding (2013), Nejad and Young (2016), and Migali (2018) find that both
economic and political institutions are significant pull factors for potential migrants. Our paper further
expands upon the insights of these studies by investigating whether emigrants self-select based on
economic, political and social institutions.
Our paper adds to the existing literature in at least three ways. First, we add social dimension as a
determinant of international migration and compare the size of its significance with that of economic
and political institutions. Earlier research includes either social dimension (White & Buehler, 2018)
or economic and political dimensions (Nejad & Young, 2016) but did not include all three variables
together. Second, we separate the pull and push factors of migration. Nejad and Young (2016) con-
centrate on pull factors of economic and political institutions, and White and Buehler (2018) focus
1 Please see Falck et al. (2018).
2 Please see Baudassé et al. (2018) for a survey of this literature.
1700
|
ARIF
on the bilateral social factors. Our paper improves upon both these studies by separating the pull and
push factors of migration, as both pull and push factors are crucial in migration decision, and it will be
interesting to evaluate whether pull factors are more important than push factors and vice versa. Third,
we explore the pull and push factors of migration based on the human capital of migrants. We expect
that the education level influences the sensitivity of potential migrants to these pull and push factors.
We use the most widely used indicators of economic, political and social institutions in our analy-
sis. For economic institutions, we use the Freedom of the World index from the Fraser Institute. The
Freedom of the World index indicates the quality of economic institutions in a country (Gwartney,
Lawson, Hall, & Murphy, 2018). For political institutions, we use the well-known Polity IV index. In
addition, we use checks and balances from Keefer and Stasavage (2003) as an indicator of political
constraint. For social institutions, we follow White and Buehler (2018) and use survival versus self-ex-
pression values and traditional versus secular-rational authority from Inglehart and Baker (2000).
Our empirical strategy includes two types of modified gravity models. Our first empirical strategy
includes converting the above three variables into ratios. We consider this approach because of the
bilateral nature of migration data and unilateral nature of the above three variables. Specifically, we
convert the economic, political and social variables into ratios between the destination and origin's
corresponding indicators. These ratios allow us to interpret coefficient values as elasticities, enabling
us to quantify and compare the effect of economic, political and social institutions on migration.3
These elasticities show the change in migration flows due to a 1% change in destination indicator,
helping us understand the effect of economic, political and social institutions; all else equal, we expect
migrants move towards destinations with better economic, political and social institutions.
Although we can observe the effects of economic, political and social institutions on migration
using the above strategy, we cannot isolate the pull factors of migration from the push factors using
the above approach. Both pull and push factors are essential components of migration. Migrants may
be moving towards destinations with improved economic, political and social conditions or leaving
origin countries with deteriorated economic, political and social conditions. The ratio-scale model
does not separate these pull and push effects. To isolate pull and push effects, we employ our second
empirical strategy. This strategy includes using the dyadic migration flow as a dependent variable and
monadic economic, political and social institutions as main explanatory variables. In addition, we test
the pull and push factors of migration using the Alesina, Harnoss, and Rapoport (2016) two-period
panel data model. Furthermore, we test the robustness of our cross-sectional results by using Hofstede's
six dimensions of culture and by splitting our sample based on the income levels of the origin and
destination countries.4
We test the effect of economic, political and social institutions on migration using bilateral mi-
gration data of 103 origin and destination countries. Our migration data come from Artuc, Docquier,
Özden, and Parsons (2015), who present global bilateral migration flows by gender and education
levels during the period 1990–2000, allowing us to test the effect of economic, political and social
institutions on three types of migration flows: total, college and non-college migration. We expect that
potential educated migrants may be more sensitive to the origin and destination countries' economic,
political and social institutions.
We use the Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood (PPML) estimator as our preferred estimation
method. There are several advantages to using PPML in this context. First, PPML accounts for zero
observations, which increases the number of observations by about 100%. Zero migration flows may
3 See Ashby (2010).
4 These robustness tests are presented in the Appendix S1.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT