The Deepwater Horizon Oil Spill and Seafood Prices

Date01 November 2010
Author
11-2010 NEWS & ANALYSIS 40 ELR 11111
The Deepwater Horizon Oil
Spill and Seafood Prices
by David A. Argue, Ph.D.
Dr. David A. Argue is a Corporate Vice President and Principal of Economists Incorporated in Washington, D.C. He is
one of the authors of the study of Alaska seafood prices after the Exxon Valdez oil spill that is discussed in this Article.
The Deepwater Horizon oil spill in the Gulf of Mexico
is a disaster of major proportions. e commercial
and natural resources damages that will arise from
the spill may ultimately be similarly signicant. e Exxon
Valdez oil spill in 1989 is often compared as the closest, if
imperfect, historical example of how the Gulf spill will be
treated. After the Exxon Valdez spill, shermen claimed pure
economic dama ges related to alleged depression of seafood
prices in addition to losses from forgone catch in closed
sheries. ese types of pure economic losses are a llowed
under the Oil Pollution Act (OPA) of 19901 and are likely
to be among those at issue in the Deepwater Horizon spill.
To quantif y such claims, it will be necessary to estimate
the seafood prices that would have prevailed if the spill had
not occurred. A study prepared for the Trans-Alaska Pipe-
line Liability Fund after the Exxon Valdez spill undertook a
comprehensive, multi-model estimation of price eects for
12 species of seafood in several sheries at dierent levels
of production.2 It based the estimation of price eects on
the fu ndamental supply and demand forces that determine
prices of Alaska seafood. is modeling approach could serve
as a template for the pure economic losses arising from the
Deepwater Horizon oil spill.
I. Pure Economic Losses
For both practical and historical reasons, the fu ll measure of
damages is not a llowed in claims following some accidents.
Damages from an accident that have in the past been d isal-
lowed for some parties following an oil spill are those charac-
terized as “pure economic losses.” is term refers to a loss of
earnings from an accident that is unrelated to any accident-
caused injury to the victim’s property. In the context of an oil
spill, these pure economic losses might include the lost prots
of shermen who were unable to access a shery that was
closed because of contamination. No injury occurred to the
shermen’s vessels, gear, or other property, but they lost earn-
ings in any event. Simila rly, a holiday resort may suer pure
economic losses from an oil spill if swimming o its beaches
1. 33 U.S.C. §§2701-2761, ELR S. OPA §§1001-7001.
2. B M. O  ., T E   D: T EXXON VALDEZ
O S (1995).
is prohibited because of fouled water. In principle, pure eco-
nomic losses can be quantied as the unit volume of lost sales
valued at the appropriate market price, less the costs of mak-
ing the goods or services available. e appropriate price for
valuing t he lost sales is the price that would have prevailed
had the accident not occurred. Other than some legal issues
of whether both the shermen a nd the resort owner have
compensable claims under maritime law (or, more relevantly
since 1990, under the OPA), there is little that is unusual
about such a damage claim.
A more distinctive claim of pure economic loss from an oil
spill relates solely to prices. Such a claim may involve allega-
tions that the accident adversely aected prices even for par-
ties that did not lose unit sales. It may also aect the correct
valuation for those that did lose sales. Damage claims for
price declines of this nature were raised by Alaska shermen
following the Exxon Valdez oil spill and could be brought
in relation to the Deepwater Horizon oil spill in the Gulf
of Mexico. e OPA allows commercial entities to claim
“[d]amages equal to the loss of prots or impairment of earn-
ing capacity due to the injury, destruction or loss of real
property, personal property, or natural resources, which shall
be recoverable by any claimant.”3 is language in the statute
could be interpreted to include price depression even without
any reduction in seafood harvests. Because the OPA was not
in eect at the time of the Exxon Valdez spill, the shermen’s
claims of depressed prices were adjudicated under maritime
law, which normally bars pure economic losses. e sher-
men maintained a right to sue, however, under the “Oppen
exception” to Robins Dry Dock & Repair C. v. Flint.4
Whether an oil spill actually creates price eects on sea-
food is a question that requires empirical study, and this
Article focuses on methods for determining whether seafood
prices were aected by an oil spill. It is worthwhile, however,
to put that in the context of other damages that might be
claimed under the OPA. e ty pes of damages under the
OPA are generally classied as follows5:
4. See Robins Dry Dock & Repair C. v. Flint, 275 U.S. 303 (1927) (Holmes,
J.) and Union Oil Co. et al. v. James J. Oppen et al., 501 F.2d 558 (9th Cir.
1974).
Copyright © 2010 Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, DC. reprinted with permission from ELR®, http://www.eli.org, 1-800-433-5120.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT