The Consequences of Ignorance in Regulatory Design: The Ethical Duty to be a Realist

AuthorAndrew P. Morriss
PositionProfessor, Bush School of Government & Public Service and School of Law, Texas A&M University
Pages717-739
The Consequences of Ignorance in Regulatory
Design: The Ethical Duty to be a Realist
ANDREW P. MORRISS
*
ABSTRACT
Regulators have a duty to be realistic in the design of new regulatory solu-
tions. This includes taking account of costs, effectiveness, and the capacity of
the government which will be charged with implementing the proposed solution.
Not considering these factors leads to failures which may well worsen the situa-
tion the regulation was supposed to improve. Using three case studies of regula-
tory measures, this Article explores the requirements of the duty to be realistic.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 717
I. THREE EXAMPLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 721
A. Externality-Reduction Regulation: Diesel Engines. . . . . . . . . 721
B. Anti-Monopoly Regulation: Public Utility Pricing . . . . . . . . . 723
C. Preventing Evasion of Regulation: Anti-Tax-Avoidance
Measures. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 725
II. MULTI-DIMENSIONAL REGULATORY ANALYSIS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 728
III. GOVERNANCE CAPACITY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 730
IV. MULTI-DIMENSIONAL REGULATORY ANALYSIS (AGAIN) . . . . . . . . . 733
CONCLUSION. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 738
INTRODUCTION
Several decades of teaching and writing about regulation have left me con-
cerned about the lack of progress in the academic literature on regulation. Both
popular and academic discussions of regulation usually portray regulatory
717
* Professor, Bush School of Government & Public Service and School of Law, Texas A&M
University. A.B., Princeton; J.D., M.Pub.Aff., The University of Texas at Austin; Ph.D. (Economics) M.
I.T.; M.Ed.Pysch., Texas A&M University. Thanks to Susan Dudley, Roger Meiners, Julia Woislaw,
and participants in the symposium for comments on earlier drafts. © 2021, Andrew P. Morriss.
choices as conflicts between lax and strict regulation.
1
Portraying regulatory
choices this way simplifies the narrative and makes telling a regulatory or deregu-
latory story much easier. It provides a villain: either an evil bureaucrat (seeking
to crush entrepreneurial activity by making regulations too strict) or a corporate
profiteer (seeking to despoil the landscape and poison workers and neighbors by
pressuring governments into making regulation too lax). It also provides a
hero: either the publicly spirited reformer seeking toughregulations on bad
actors or a deregulatory crusader liberating the entrepreneurial spirit of economic
actors crushed by oppressive regulation. The public can easily tell for whom to
root. The solution is similarly straightforward: If only the right regulators could
be put in charge of the process, we could achieve the optimal level of regulation.
Economists (like me) bear some of the blame for the dominance of this sim-
plistic narrative. Most economics courses and publications illustrate regulatory
policy issues with a graph like Figure 1. The plot indicates that the presence of an
externality has caused the market to produce a suboptimal result. By applying the
right policy (a tax, a subsidy, a quantity limit, etc.), regulators can move society
to an optimal equilibrium, ideally a Pareto-optimal one. More advanced econom-
ics texts add some fancy math, but they tell essentially the same story: society is
not at the optimal equilibrium. Applying the right policy can fix that. Therefore, a
regulation that is neither too lax nor too strict should be created and bring us
closer to equilibrium.
1. The examples are so numerous that a footnote seems superfluous. Here are some representative
examples from the past two years across diverse fields, including environmental law, energy law,
financial law, and sports law. See, e.g., Hannah Ford-Stille, Regulated and Hydrated: A Case for
Regulating Bottled Water, 60 SANTA CLARA L. REV. 325, 347 (2020) ([L]ax and inconsistent
groundwater regulations combined with FDA’s dereliction of enforcement will ultimately converge into
a larger issuehealth effects.); Yosra Abid, Reflection on Shale Gas Fracking Risk Assessment and
Management in the United States, 11 WASH. J. ENVT L. & POLY 1, 11 (2020) (Lax fracking
regulations are at the origin of fracking-data gaps and absence of reporting requirements. Risk
assessment tools (e.g. predictive models) have purposefully been omitted in statutes and regulations
governing fracking activities.); Michael Greenberger, Too Big to FailU.S. Banks’ Regulatory
Alchemy: Converting an Obscure Agency Footnote into an At WillNullification of Dodd-Frank’s
Regulation of the Multi-Trillion Dollar Financial Swaps Market, 14 J. BUS. & TECH. L. 197, 379 (2019)
(Because of the laxity in EU financial regulatory rules, EU country banking systems have shown
substantial weakness under the EU financial regulatory paradigm.); Robert I. Correales, Broken Bodies
and Broken Dreams: How Social Safety Net Programs Subsidize Professional Boxing and the Need to
Improve Legal and Health Protections for Prizefighters, 19 TEX. REV. ENT. & SPORTS L. 107, 119
(2019) (The inadequate patchwork of state-by-state regulation had enabled unscrupulous characters to
shop for states with lax regulations, endangering the economic and personal well-being of professional
boxers.).
718 THE GEORGETOWN JOURNAL OF LAW & PUBLIC POLICY [Vol. 19:717

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT