The conditional relation between dispersion and return

Published date01 September 2013
AuthorShrikant P. Jategaonkar,Rıza Demirer
Date01 September 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2013.04.004
The conditional relation between dispersion and return
Rıza Demirer , Shrikant P. Jategaonkar
Department of Economics & Finance, Southern Illinois University Edwardsville, Edwardsville, IL 620261102, United States
abstractarticle info
Article history:
Received 21 June 2012
Received in revised form 28 February 2013
Accepted 17 April 2013
Available online 25 April 2013
JEL Classication:
G11
G12
Keywords:
Return dispersion
Conditional pricing effect
Asymmetric risk
Asset pricing
The main goal of this paper is to examine the conditional pricing effect of return dispersion on the cross section
of returns. We observe a systematic conditional relation between dispersion and return even after controlling
for market, size and book-to-market factors. However, we nd that return dispersion risk is asymmetrically
priced with a signicantly positive premium observed during periods of large market gains only. The ndings
are found to be robust to alternative conditional specications of market returns, suggesting asymmetric pric-
ing effect of the return dispersion factor. We provide alternative explanations for the systematic risk captured
by the return dispersion factor and discuss implications for portfolio management and corporate decisions.
© 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
The relation between security returns and the different systematic
risk factors driving them has been extensively studied in the literature.
Starting with the Capital Asset Pricing Model of Sharpe (1964),Lintner
(1965) and Mossin (1966), a great deal of research has been devoted
to understanding how systematic risk factors drive the cross section
of returns.
1
In the asset pricing literature, the Fama-French three-
factor model that incorporates the market, rm size and book-to-
market factors has now become the dominant model.
2
In a recent
study, Jiang (2010) reports that return dispersion, dened as the
cross sectional standard deviation of stock returns around the market
average, carries a signicant positive price of risk. Using data on U.S.
stocks, he nds that stocks with greater sensitivities to return disper-
sion yield higher average returns, suggesting a two-factor asset
pricing model that incorporates return dispersion and the market re-
turn. He further notes that the return dispersion factor dominates
the book-to-market factor in the Fama-French model and concludes
that return dispersion captures two dimensions of systematic risk:
the business cycle and economic restructuring.
Several studies in the literature have examined return dispersion
from different angles. These studies suggest that return dispersion is
associated witheconomic uncertainty and the business cycle (Christie
& Huang, 1994; Loungani, Rush, & Tave, 1990), market volatility
(Bekaert and Harvey, 1997, 2000; Stivers, 2003), and idiosyncratic
volatility (Connolly & Stivers, 2006 and Stivers, 2003). Stivers (2003)
and Connolly and Stivers (2006) establish a link between return dis-
persion andaggregate market volatilityand nd that return dispersion
provides signals about future aggregate market volatility. Stivers and
Sun (2010) document a link between the time variation in the value
and momentum premiums and the variation in the market's cross-
sectional return dispersion. More recently, Jiang (2010) takes these
studies one step further and incorporates return dispersion into an
asset-pricingmodel and shows that returndispersion is in fact a priced
risk factor.
On the other hand,a growing body of literaturesuggests the notion
of asymmetric risk and asymmetric risk premiums reected in the
cross-section of stock returns.
3
Examining U.S. stock returns, Ang,
Chen, and Xing (2006) show that asymmetric risk is in fact priced
with a signicant downside risk premium observed over the cross
section of returns. More recently, Huang, Liu, Rhee, and Wub (2012)
report a signicantly positive extreme downside risk premium even
after controlling for systematic risk factors including market, size and
book-to-market ratio. In another strand of literature, studies including
Christie and Huang (1994) and Duffee (2001) report asymmetries in
observed cross-sectional return dispersions with respect to market
movements. Christie and Huang (1994) nd that return dispersion is
Review of Financial Economics 22 (2013) 125134
Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 618 650 2939; fax: + 1 618 650 3047.
E-mail addresses: rdemire@siue.edu (R. Demirer), sjatega@siue.edu (S.P. Jategaonkar).
1
See,for example, Chen, Roll,and Ross (1986),Haugenand Baker (1996),andBrennan,
Chordia,and Subrahmanyam (1998), amongothers.
2
See Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1996).
3
See for example Longin and Solnik (2001),Silvapulle and Granger (2001),Ang and
Chen (2002), and Campbell, Koedijk, and Kofman (2002) among others.
1058-3300/$ see front matter © 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2013.04.004
Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect
Review of Financial Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rfe

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT