The Conditional Effect of Electoral Systems and Intraparty Candidate Selection Processes on Parties' Behavior

AuthorYael Shomer
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12141
Date01 February 2017
Published date01 February 2017
YAEL SHOMER
Tel-Aviv University
The Conditional Effect of Electoral
Systems and Intraparty Candidate
Selection Processes on
Parties’ Behavior
How do electoral systems and intraparty candidate selection procedures affect
party unity? In this article, I distinguish theoretically and empirically between electoral
systems and candidate selections and argue that the influence of selection processes on
parties’ behavior is conditional on electoral system (and vice versa). Measuring parties’
unity using Rice and weighted Rice scores, and applying hierarchical models to a new
data set of 249 parties in 24 countries, I find support for the claim that the influence of
selection processes on behavior is greater under electoral systems that encourage perso-
nal vote-seeking incentives than under electoral systems that encourage party
centeredness.
Maintaining a unif‌ied party voting record is an important objective
for both party leaders and rank-and-f‌ile members. Unif‌ied parties aid pol-
icy implementation and improve stability in both parliamentary and
presidential systems. Without party unity, in presidential systems, the
president’s base of legislative support becomes less stable and predict-
able, whereas in parliamentary systems government survival might be
threatened. Additionally, a unif‌ied party record helps enhance the party’s
electoral performance, as it creates a clear brand name with which voters
identify. Lastly, within the legislative arena, a unif‌ied party record
reduces transaction costs in log rolling, increases policy-making capabil-
ities, decreases legislative unpredictability, and amplif‌ies legislative
eff‌iciency. Indeed, disciplined-unif‌ied parties are regarded as one of the
pillars of the responsible party government doctrine (Ranney 1954).
What explains the degree to which parties behave as a unif‌ied
actor? Scholars have long argued that electoral systems and intraparty
candidate selection processes (i.e., the manner by which a party decides
who can represent it on its ballot) shape the balance legislators strike
between emphasizing their unique personal reputation and the collective
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 42, 1, February 2017 63
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12141
V
C2016 Washington University in St. Louis
reputation of their parties. As legislators seek to maximize their probabil-
ity of getting (re)-elected, they adhere to the incentives and constraints
electoral systems and candidate selection procedures produce and
choose to either vote with their copartisans and sustain a unif‌ied party
voting record or vote against them weakening their party’s unity (Carey
and Shugart 1995; Hazan 2000).
This article seeks to examine how extralegislative institutional
arrangements—i.e., electoral systems and intraparty candidate selection
processes—affect parties’ behavior and legislators’ tendency to maintain
a unif‌ied party record. To date, most scholars consider the effect of elec-
toral systems and selection processes separately. It has been argued that
the more permissive the electoral system is, the less unif‌ied parties will
be (see Andr
e, Depauw, and Shugart 2014). Similarly, inclusive and
decentralized candidate selection processes have been hypothesized to
induce a dis-unif‌ied party voting record (Bowler, Farrell, and Katz 1999;
Hazan 2000; Hazan and Rahat 2006). However, numerous examples
might cast doubt on this simplistic depiction.
The Brazilian left-wing parties’ (e.g., the Worker’s Party) high lev-
els of unity present a puzzle. Brazil’s open-list PR system should have,
according to the electoral systems’ separate-effect hypothesis, induced
undisciplined and dis-unif‌ied parties. However, whereas some scholars
(e.g., Ames 1995) characterize Brazilian parties as undisciplined, others
(e.g., Figueiredo and Limongi 2000) f‌ind highly unif‌ied parties, espe-
cially within the left wing (Mainwaring and Lin
an 1997) (see Amorim
Neto [2002] for discussion about the debate). Why would parties under
the Brazilian permissive electoral system enjoy high levels of unity?
Mainwaring and Lin
an argue that restrictive selection procedures might
solve this puzzle and claim that even under open-list PR systems
“[i]f central party leaders control the selection process, individual
legislators ...are more likely to toe the party line” (1997, 476).
Similarly, despite variation in selection procedures used in
Argentina (De-Luca, Jones, and Tula 2002) and despite expectations for
provincial effects on parties’ behavior, Jones and Hwang f‌ind that “no
provincial effects are detected” (2005, 273). They explain the seemingly
unif‌ied parties’ and legislators’ behavior using the negative agenda-
control thesis presented by the American cartel theory (Cox and McCub-
bins 2005). However, I suggest a different explanation—a conditional
theory: given the closed-list PR electoral system Argentina uses, we
would not expect local primaries and provincial control to affect legisla-
tors’ behavior and parties’ unity levels dramatically.
As a last motivating example I will present Israel. Israel’s parties
used over the years numerous forms of candidate selection procedures
64 Yael Shomer
from the most exclusive and centralized manner, in which one leader (or
rabbi) selects the list, to an inclusive selection via party primaries. If the
separate effect of selection processes on parties’ unity levels is correct,
one should have observed that those parties that select via primaries
exhibited lower levels of unity compared to parties selecting in a
centralized restrictive way. However, this conclusion is not supported by
data (Rahat 2007).
1
To solve these puzzles and explain why other empirical tests of the
separate effect of elections and selection on parties’ behavior yield
inconclusive support, I suggest a theory about the combined conditional
effect of elections and selections. Both electoral systems and candidate
selection processes have the theoretical separate ability to induce a uni-
f‌ied collective voting record. Thus, if the electoral system incentivizes
legislators to toe their party’s line, the effect of the candidate selection
procedure, and especially democratized processes, will be muted. This is
because the electoral system will ensure a unif‌ied party record regardless
of the type of selection processes a party uses. Under these conditions,
therefore, party leaders may afford democratizing candidate selection
processes, knowing their negative effect on party unity will be minimal.
By the same token, if the manner by which legislators are selected by
their parties guarantees they maintain a unif‌ied voting record, then the
effect of electoral systems on behavior would be minimal. Party leaders,
however, may use restrictive selection processes to attenuate the effect
of electoral systems that encourage legislators to break the party line,
and ensure—even under permissive electoral systems—a unif‌ied voting
record. When selection processes are centralized and restrictive, party
leaders may either apriorichoose a party slate that holds similar ideo-
logical preferences, or they may threaten to punish reluctant legislators
by not renominating them in the next election cycle. Hence, restrictive
candidate selection processes may overcome the personal vote-seeking
incentives produced by an electoral system. Therefore, I claim that the
inf‌luence of selection processes on parties’ unity levels is conditional on
the type of electoral system a country has and similarly, that the effect of
electoral systems on a party’s voting record is conditioned by the manner
by which the party selects its candidates.
After presenting the current state of the literature, which motivates
the necessity for the elaborated conditional hypothesis, I test the condi-
tional effect of electoral systems and selection processes on party unity
using a varying-intercept varying-slope hierarchical model, where par-
ties are nested within country-sessions. This multilevel structure allows
me to account for the fact that selection procedures and electoral systems
are distinct institutions that operate usually at distinct levels: Candidate
65Electoral Systems and Selection Processes

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT