The competitive effects of S&P 500 Index revisions

AuthorSheng‐Syan Chen,Yueh‐Hsiang Lin
Published date01 July 2018
Date01 July 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12312
DOI: 10.1111/jbfa.12312
The competitive effects of S&P 500 Index revisions
Sheng-Syan Chen1Yueh-Hsiang Lin2
1Departmentof Finance, College of Commerce,
NationalChengchi University, Taipei 11605,
Tai w a n
2Departmentof Finance, College of Business,
NationalTaipei University of Business, Taipei
10051,Taiwan
Correspondence
Yueh-HsiangLin, Department of Finance,
Collegeof Business, National TaipeiUniversity
ofBusiness, No. 321, Sec. 1, Jinan Rd., Taipei,
Taiwan.
Email:nelsonlin@ntub.edu.tw
JELClassification: G14, G31, L22
Abstract
Firms added to the S&P 500 Indexgain a competitive advantage over
their non-S&P 500 industry competitors. They experience positive
stockvaluation effects at the expense of competitors. The inclusion is
associated with both reductions in financial constraints and the cost
of equity and increases in capital investment for the newly added
firms. When the increase in capital investment is greater, they gain
more market share and enjoy better valuation effects. Rivals’ share
price responses are negatively related to the announcement effect
of the newly added firm. Deletions from the index, however,do not
have symmetric effects.
KEYWORDS
announcement effect, capital investment, competitive effect, index
revision, marketshare
1INTRODUCTION
An extensiveliterature shows a positive share price effect for firms newly added to Standard & Poor's (S&P) 500 Index
at the time such an announcement is made. The early research argues that the positive effect arises from a shift in
the downward-sloping demand curve for the new additions, either because securities are not close substitutes for one
another (Beneish & Whaley,1996; Lynch & Mendenhall, 1997; Shleifer, 1986), or because investorswho accommodate
demand shifts must be compensated for trading costs and risks (Harris & Gurel, 1986). More recent studies suggest
that the increase in share prices for the newly added stocks may be explained by improvedliquidity (Becker-Blease &
Paul,2006; Chordia, 2008; Hedge & McDermott, 2003); enhanced investor awareness (Chen, Noronha, & Singal, 2004;
Zhou, 2011); reduced cost of equity (Baran & King, 2012); and added information about better cash flow prospects
conveyed to the market (Denis, McConnell, Ovtchinnikov, & Yu, 2003). Our research adds a new dimension to this
literature in that we relate enhanced competitive advantages to index inclusion itself and consider the competitive
impact of index inclusion on industry peers.
The competitive effects of index inclusion have important implications for investors, industry peers, and newly
included firms. A simple look at the stock price reaction for index inclusion firms does not reveal whether other firms
in the same industry are affected by inclusion announcements. Investors making portfolio allocation decisions would
like to know how the inclusion of one firm affects the stock prices of its competitors. The share price effects for the
new index firms alone also do not tell us how other firms in the same industry are affected by changes in the compet-
itive structure of the industry. Firms competing with new indexfirms need to know how to respond to such changes.
Finally,new index firms might benefit from reduced agency and information asymmetry problems because of increased
J Bus Fin Acc. 2018;45:997–1027. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jbfa c
2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 997
998 CHEN ANDLIN
monitoring and greater production of information by investors and analysts following the inclusion (Baran & King,
2012; Chen et al., 2004; Denis et al., 2003). These advantages might give such firms more access to capital markets
and thus financing for future investments (e.g.,Campello et al., 2010; Denis & Sibilkov,2010; Hubbard, 1998; Li, 2011).
A reduced cost of equity resulting from improved stock liquidity and enhanced investor awareness also expands the
set of investment opportunities for new index firms (Baran & King, 2012; Becker-Blease & Paul, 2006; Chen et al.,
2004). Thus, new index firms gain a competitive advantage over their industry peers due to increasing investmentin
the product market (e.g., Almeida, Campello, & Weisbach, 2004; Byoun & Xu, 2016; Campello, 2003; Chen & Wang,
2012; Chevalier& Scharfstein, 1996; Froot, Scharfstein, & Stein, 1993). In other words, newly included firms may enjoy
increased product market share and improvedshare price performance, advantages directly related to index inclusion
itself.
We examine the stock performance of newly included firms and their industry peers around S&P 500 Index addi-
tions over the period 19762011. We confirm that the average announcement-period abnormal return for newly
included firms is statistically positive. Wealso find that industry rivals that are not included in the S&P 500 Index expe-
rience a significantly negative share price response. The results suggest that index inclusion permits the newly added
firms to gain a competitive advantage overindustry rivals.
We investigate how new index firms can successfully compete against their industry peers. We confirm previous
findings that newly added firms without S&P rivals are associated with significant increases in share turnover,analyst
following, institutional holdings, number of shareholders, and capital investment, and significant declines in shadow
cost and cost of equity.1We add to the literature by showing that newly added firms also experience significantly
reduced financial constraints, suggesting that index inclusion is associated with better access to financing. Increased
stockliquidity, improved investor awareness, diminished agency,and information asymmetry problems associated with
inclusion together are related to reduced cost of equity, financial constraints, and increased investment for newly
added firms.
The evidence remains valid for industry-adjusted figures, indicating that post-addition changes in the characteris-
tics of newly added firms cannot be explained entirely byindustry factors.
Wefurther show that newly added firms are associated with significant market share gains surrounding index inclu-
sion. The expansion in market share is positively and significantly related to the change in these firms’ capital invest-
ment. The evidence indicates that index inclusion advantages newly added firms in the product market. Our findings
continue to hold when we use the industry-adjusted change in market share or when we replace the change in market
share with sales growth.
We investigate whether the announcement return for new index firms is related to the competitive effects in the
product market. If the change in capital investment following indexinclusion is positively related to the market share
gain for newly added firms, their announcement-period abnormal stock returns should also be positively related to
their investment change. As expected, we document a positive and significant relation between the announcement
return of newly added firms without S&P rivals and their capital investment change surrounding index inclusion. This
result suggests that the favorableshare price responses of newly added firms are related to their stronger competitive
positions in the product market.
We also examinewhether rivals’ share price responses to index inclusion are related to the announcement effect of
new indexfirms. As the announcement return of newly added firms without S&P rivals is positively related to their cap-
ital investment change around index inclusion, the announcement return should be negativelyrelated to rivals’ share
price responses. We document that rivals’ share price responses around inclusion announcements are negatively and
significantly related to the announcement-period abnormal return of newly added firms. The evidence indicates that
the share price responses of industry rivals are more unfavorable when theysuffer more competitive disadvantage in
the product market arising from the higher investmentof newly added firms.
1See,for example, Baran and King (2012), Becker-Blease and Paul (2006), Chan, Kot, and Tang(2013), Chen et al. (2004), and Denis et al. (2003).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT