The Commerce Requirement in Tying Law

AuthorChristopher R. Leslie
PositionChancellor's Professor of Law, University of California Irvine School of Law
Pages2135-2160
2135
The Commerce Requirement in Tying
Law
Christopher R. Leslie
I. INTRODUCTION ........................................................................... 2136
II. THE ORIGINAL FUNCTION OF THE COMMERCE ELEMENT IN TYING
LAW ............................................................................................. 2137
A. THE LEGAL TEST FOR IDENTIFYING WHICH TYING ARRANGEMENTS
ARE ANTICOMPETITIVE .......................................................... 2137
B. THE COMMERCE REQUIREMENT AND DISTINGUISHING
ANTICOMPETITIVE TYING ARRANGEMENTS ............................. 2140
C. PROBLEMS WITH USING DOLLAR VOLUME AS A PROXY FOR
ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS .................................................... 2142
III. THE EVOLUTION OF THE COMMERCE ELEMENT ......................... 2144
A. THE JURISDICTIONAL INQUIRY IN TYING CLAIMS ..................... 2145
B. THE COMMERCE ELEMENT BECOMES JURISDICTIONAL ............ 2146
C. ONE ELEMENT, SEVERAL VARIATIONS ..................................... 2149
D. THE IMPLICATIONS OFAND THE ARGUMENT AGAINSTA
JURISDICTIONAL INTERPRETATION OF THE COMMERCE
ELEMENT .............................................................................. 2153
IV. FIXING THE COMMERCE ELEMENT .............................................. 2156
A. EXAMINE COMPETITIVE EFFECTS DIRECTLY ............................ 2156
B. ELIMINATE THE PER SE LABEL ............................................... 2158
C. INTERSTATE COMMERCE AS A SEPARATE ELEMENT .................. 2160
V. CONCLUSION .............................................................................. 2160
Chan cell ors Professor of Law, University of California Irvine School of Law. T he author
thanks Herbert Hovenkamp and Tony Reese for comments on earlier drafts.
2136 IOWA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 100:2135
I. INTRODUCTION
Courts condemn tying arrangements based on the assumption that firms
are leveraging their market power in one market (the “tying product market”)
in order to monopolize a second market (the “tied product market”).1 A tying
arrangement exists when a seller refuses to sell one product (the “tying
product”) unless the buyer also agrees to purchase another separate product
(the “tied product”). Tying arrangements may potentially injure competition
in numerous ways.2 For example, a tying seller may employ a tie-in to suppress
competition in the market for the tied product.3 Tying arrangements may also
create a barrier to entry into the tying product market.4 Absent proof of a
legitimate purpose for the tying arrangement that cannot be achieved
through less restrictive means, scholars have long argued thatit is a
reasonable assumption that the purpose of the seller in using a tie-in is to
restrain competition in the tied product.”5 The Supreme Court famously
asserted in Standard Stations that “[t]ying agreements serve hardly any purpo se
beyond the suppression of competition.”6 Historically, the fear that tying
arrangements were almost inherently anticompetitive led courts to condemn
some tying arrangements as per se illegal.7
Despite decades of scholarship and hundreds of published opinions,
tying law remains a confusing and controversial area of antitrust
jurisprudence.8 This Essay focuses on the least controversial element: that a
1. See Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 14–15 (1984); Christopher
R. Leslie, Cutting Through Tying Theory with Occam’s Razor: A Simple Explanation of Tying
Arrangements, 78 TUL. L. REV. 727, 732–36 (2004).
2. See Christopher R. Leslie, Tying Conspiracies, 48 WM. & MARY L. REV. 2247, 2260–76
(2007).
3. N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 11 (1958) (“[T]he vice of tying
arrangements lies in the use of economic power in one market to restrict competition on the
merits in another . . . .”); Kurt A. Strasser, An Antitrust Policy for Tying Arrangemen ts, 34 EMORY L.J.
253, 267 (1985).
4. See Christopher R. Leslie, Patent Tying, Price Discrimination, and Innovation, 77 ANTITRUST
L.J. 811, 843–44 (2011).
5. Donald F. Turner, The Validity of Tying Arrangements Under the Antitrust Laws, 72 HARV. L.
REV. 50, 62 (1958).
6. Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 305–06 (1949).
7. See Int’l Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392, 396 (1947).
8. See generally Rebecca Haw Allensworth, The Influence of the Areeda–Hovenkamp Treatise in
the Lower Courts and What It Means for Institutional Reform in Antit rust, 100 IOWA L. REV. 1919(2015);
Roger D. Blair & Christine Piette Durrance, Licensing Health Care Professionals, State Action and
Antitrust Policy, 100 IOWA L. REV. 1943 (2015); Roger D. Blair & D. Daniel Sokol, Quality-
Enhancing Merger Efficiencies, 100 IOWA L. REV. 1969 (2015); John M. Connor & Robert H. Lande,
Not Treble Damages: Cartel Recoveries Are Mostly Less Than Single Damages, 100 IOWA L. REV. 1997
(2015); Daniel A. Crane, All I Really Need to Know About Antitrust I Learned in 1912, 100 IOWA L.
REV. 2025 (2015); Keith N. Hylton, Deterrence and Antitrust Punishment: Firms Versus Agents, 100
IOWA L. REV. 2069(2015); William E. Kovacic & Marc Winerman, The Federal Trade Commission as
an Independent Agency: Autonomy, Legitimacy, and Effectiveness, 100 IOWA L. REV. 2085 (2015); Mark
A. Lemley & Christopher R. Leslie, Antitrust Arbitration and Illinois Brick, 100 IOWA L. REV. 2115

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT