The Case for a Crude Oil Price Stabilization Tax

Date01 March 2010
Author
40 ELR 10328 ENVIRONMENTAL LAW REPORTER 3-2010
The Case for a
Crude Oil Price
Stabilization Tax
by Richard A. Westin
Richard A. Westin is the Laramie Leatherman Professor
of Taxation, University of Kentucky College of Law.

Policymakers should work to place a oor under the
price of crude oil and derivates by imposing a variable
import tax on those products. A variable import tax
would give consumers and the alternative energy indus-
tries a clear price signal in order to improve their deci-
sionmaking, as well as to provide a steady price signal to
domestic energy producers. e tax would also prevent
price collapses. Although economists have debated at
oil import fees vigorously, this proposal has been over-
looked to date.
The United States lacks a coherent energ y policy and
as a result is vulnerable to wild swings in oil prices
and gradually running out of its own crude oil. Our
indierence has a number of expensive results:
• Our automobile a nd truck manu facturers cannot
predict oil prices, and therefore c annot accurately
determine what model li nes to produce. As an exam-
ple, the Toyota Prius routinely sold for thousands of
dollars more than its st icker pric e, with waiting list s
up to a year long. In fact, when oil prices spiked in
October of 2006, there was only a three-hour inven-
tory of Priuses, so Toyota expa nded its manufactur-
ing facilities, but l ater found that thanks to falling
oil pr ices it had to oer incentives to sell enough of
its hybrids.1 is is just one example of short-term
macroeconomic dislocations caused by oil price col-
lapses, which, when ag gregated, resu lt in la rge losses
to the economy.
• Because any oil supply shuto can resu lt in a danger-
ously d isruptive increase in the price and e ven avail-
ability of the fuels that we rely on, our government
considers it has to project our power globa lly, at great
expense. Because the percentage of imported oil is
steadily rising, this disadvantage ous situation is wors-
ening. Costs include those for militar y forces defend-
ing the Middle East and foreign aid to countries in
the Middle East.2 One study put the price at $7.32
per barrel.3 In addition, there is the cost of maintain-
ing t he Strateg ic Petroleum Reserve, as to wh ich the
Externa lity Subgroup and the Strategic Petroleum
Reserve Oce reportedly estimated average annual
carr ying costs between $0.50 to $0.66 per barrel of oil
in the reserve.4 Futures m arkets (which are publicly
traded) and forward markets (private arrangements
to deliver or buy) for petroleum ca n help mediate the
shocks, as can the strategic petroleum reserve (against
price spikes), but they are of limited use. e strategic
reserve is good for only a little over two months a nd
long-term f utures contracts (which can extend as far
as 84 months on the New York Mercantile Exc hange
(NY MEX)) a re expensive. Because f utures contracts
call for actual deliveries, they would be dangerous
1. Micheline Maynard,  , N.Y.
T, Feb. 8, 2007, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2007/02/08/
automobiles/08hy brid.html. Toyota’s vice president for North Am erican
marketing also st ated that need to generate demand “keeps me up at nig ht.”
Id.
2. P N. L  ., O R N’ L., O I: A A
 B  C, at S-10 (1997), available at http://www.esd.ornl.gov/
eess/energy_analysis/les/ORNL6851.pdf.
3. Darwin C. Hall,  , 20 E P’ 1089, 1094
(1992).
4. L  ., supra note 2, at S-12.
Copyright © 2010 Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, DC. reprinted with permission from ELR®, http://www.eli.org, 1-800-433-5120.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT