The Antitrust Challenge to Covenants not to Compete in Employment Contracts

AuthorEric A. Posner
PositionKirkland & Ellis Distinguished Service Professor, University of Chicago Law School
Pages165-200
THE ANTITRUST CHALLENGE TO COVENANTS NOT
TO COMPETE IN EMPLOYMENT CONTRACTS
E
RIC
A. P
OSNER
*
For many years, Jimmy John’s franchises included a covenant not to com-
pete (or “noncompete”) in the employment contracts signed by their workers,
including entry-level sandwich makers. The noncompete barred employees
from working for any sandwich shop within three miles of any Jimmy John’s
franchise for two years.
1
Because thousands of Jimmy John’s outlets are scat-
tered across the United States, with most of them concentrated in cities, the
noncompete barred sandwich-shop work over huge swathes of the country,
including major urban areas. The disclosure of the noncompete arrangement
caused a public outcry and litigation. The noncompetes were very likely ille-
gal because they did not protect trade secrets or customer goodwill,
2
but may
well have deterred low-income workers from seeking higher-paying jobs from
Jimmy John’s competitors. Jimmy John’s eventually settled litigation brought
by state attorneys general and withdrew the noncompetes.
3
Noncompetes are clauses in employment contracts that forbid workers to
work for competitors of their former employer, for a certain period of time
* Kirkland & Ellis Distinguished Service Professor, University of Chicago Law School.
Thanks to Steve Salop and Evan Starr for helpful comments, to an audience at the University of
Chicago Law School faculty workshop for questions, and to several anonymous referees for their
helpful suggestions. Particular thanks to Randy Picker for his challenging questions. And thanks
to Maia Dunlap and Justin Taleisnik for valuable research assistance.
1
Dave Jamieson, Jimmy John’s Makes Low-Wage Workers Sign ‘Oppressive’ Noncompete
Agreements, H
UFF
P
OST
(Oct. 13, 2014), www.huffpost.com/entry/jimmy-johns-non-compete_n_
5978180.
2
See discussion infra Parts I.B, II.A.2.
3
See, e.g., Press Release, Office of the Attorney General for the State of Illinois, Madigan
Announces Settlement with Jimmy John’s for Imposing Unlawful Non-Compete Agreements
(Dec. 7, 2016), www.illinoisattorneygeneral.gov/pressroom/2016_12/20161207.html; Press Re-
lease, Office of the Attorney General for the State of New York, A.G. Schneiderman Announces
Settlement with Jimmy John’s to Stop Including Non-Compete Agreements in Hiring Packets
(June 22, 2016), www.ag.ny.gov/press-release/2016/ag-schneiderman-announces-settlement-jim
my-johns-stop-including-non-compete.
165
166 A
NTITRUST
L
AW
J
OURNAL
[Vol. 83
and over a defined geographic area.
4
Despite its traditional orientation toward
laissez faire, the common law has always regarded noncompetes as restraints
of trade, and hence presumptively unenforceable. Noncompetes are subject to
a reasonableness test: a noncompete is enforceable only if the restrictions it
imposes on the worker are no more burdensome than necessary to protect the
employer’s legitimate business interest—usually, in protection of trade secrets
or customer goodwill. In practice, however, noncompetes are frequently en-
forced, or simply not challenged, and may deter workers from quitting even
when they are unenforceable. New research reveals that they appear in mil-
lions of employment contracts, and may deter workers from quitting and seek-
ing alternative employment.
5
While noncompetes were traditionally
understood to be justified only for specialized and well-compensated employ-
ees, it turns out they are frequently imposed on low-skill employees like the
Jimmy John’s sandwich makers.
6
In recent years, controversies over noncompetes and the new academic re-
search that documents their prevalence have put the noncompete on the public
agenda. Congress and state legislatures have considered or passed new laws
restricting noncompetes, and presidential candidates have touted proposals for
reform.
7
The Federal Trade Commission has held hearings on whether it
should regulate noncompetes under Section 5;
8
the Department of Justice has
intervened in cases involving no-poaching clauses in franchise agreements
which function similarly to noncompetes.
9
State attorneys general in Illinois,
4
My focus is on “employee non-competes.” I do not address the use of noncompetes in other
settings, for example, as part of the sale of a business. I also exclude franchise no-poach clauses
from the general discussion.
5
See Evan Starr, J.J. Prescott & Norman Bishara, Noncompetes in the U.S. Labor Force 1–4
(U. Mich. L. & Econ. Research Paper No. 18-013, 2019). The authors found that 18.1% of the
U.S. labor force, or roughly 28 million people, were subject to a noncompete agreement as of
2014, and nearly 40% have signed a noncompete at some point in their careers. Id. at 2.
6
See id. at 16–17. Approximately 14.3% of workers without a bachelor’s degree were subject
to noncompetes in 2014, compared to 26.6% of those with bachelor’s degrees. Id.
7
See infra Part I.D.
8
See, e.g., Fed. Trade Comm’n Event Calendar, Non-Competes in the Workplace: Examin-
ing Antitrust and Consumer Protection Issues (Jan. 9, 2020), www.ftc.gov/news-events/events-
calendar/non-competes-workplace-examining-antitrust-consumer-protection-issues.
9
The Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice filed Statements of Interest in three
private no-poach cases filed by former employees against Auntie Anne’s, Arby’s, and Carl’s Jr.,
respectively. Corrected Statement of Interest of the United States, Harris v. CJ Star, LLC, 2:18-
cv-00247 (E.D. Wash. Mar. 8, 2019); Corrected Statement of Interest of the United States, Rich-
mond v. Bergey Pullman Inc., 2:18-cv-00246 (E.D. Wash. Mar. 8, 2019); Corrected Statement of
Interest of the United States, Stigar v. Dough Dough, Inc., 2:18-cv-00244 (E.D. Wash. Mar. 8,
2019).
2020] A
NTITRUST AND
N
ONCOMPETES
167
Washington, and New York have challenged noncompete agreements under
state consumer protection laws, and won several settlements.
10
In this article, I argue that legal regulation of noncompetes should be
strengthened because of their adverse effect on competition.
11
The common
law approach is inadequate because employers do not face substantial sanc-
tions if a court invalidates a noncompete, and—more significantly—the com-
mon law does not provide the right approach for evaluating noncompetes.
Because noncompetes pose a threat to competition, the analytic lens of anti-
trust law should be used. Antitrust law focuses on the market effects of
noncompetes and provides for a significant deterrent in the form of treble
damages when employers abuse them. However, antitrust enforcement has
rarely been successful because of difficulties of proof. Accordingly, I argue
for a stronger antitrust regime that incorporates presumptions derived from the
empirical literature on noncompetes and related labor market behavior. The
law should treat noncompetes as presumptively illegal, allowing employers to
rebut the presumption if they can prove that the noncompetes they use will
benefit rather than harm their workers.
Noncompetes have received significant attention from legal scholars and
economists. One body of research stems from Ronald Gilson’s hypothesis that
by reducing employee mobility, noncompetes prevent cross-fertilization of
ideas across firms, in turn reducing innovation and growth.
12
Another group of
articles discuss the antitrust analysis of noncompetes, but these articles are
more than 30 years old, have had no influence, and do not incorporate the
latest findings from economists.
13
The most significant body of work, which is
10
See, e.g., Robert Channick, Low-Wage Workers Free to Quit Chicago-Area Payday Lender
for New Jobs After State Ends ‘Unfair’ Noncompete Agreements, C
HI
. T
RIB
. (Jan. 7, 2019), www
.chicagotribune.com/business/ct-biz-illinois-payday-lender-noncompete-20190107-story.html.
11
I briefly touched on some of these arguments in a short piece written for a general audience.
See Eric A. Posner, The Anticompetitive Effects of Covenants Not to Compete, C
OMPETITION
P
OL
Y
I
NT
L
(Jan. 23, 2020), www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/the-anticompetitive-ef
fects-of-covenants-not-to-compete/.
12
Ronald J. Gilson, The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial Districts: Silicon
Valley, Route 128, and Covenants Not to Compete, 74 N.Y.U. L. R
EV
. 575, 578 (1998). See also
A
LAN
H
YDE
, W
ORKING IN
S
ILICON
V
ALLEY
: E
CONOMIC AND
L
EGAL
A
NALYSIS OF A
H
IGH
-V
E-
LOCITY
L
ABOR
M
ARKET
(2003); A
NNE
L
EE
S
AXENIAN
, R
EGIONAL
A
DVANTAGE
: C
ULTURE AND
C
OMPETITION IN
S
ILICON
V
ALLEY AND
R
OUTE
128, at 2–4 (1996); On Amir & Orly Lobel, Driv-
ing Performance: A Growth Theory of Noncompete Law, 16 S
TAN
. T
ECH
. L. R
EV
. 833, 861–63,
866 (2013); Bruce Fallick et al., Job-Hopping in Silicon Valley: Some Evidence Concerning the
Micro-Foundations of a High Technology Cluster, 88 R
EV
. E
CON
. & S
TATS
. 472, 472–73 (2006);
Sampsa Samila & Olav Sorenson, Noncompete Covenants: Incentives to Innovate or Impedi-
ments to Growth, 57 M
GMT
. S
CI
. 425, 427 (2011).
13
See, e.g., Harvey J. Goldschmid, Antitrust’s Neglected Stepchild: A Proposal for Dealing
with Restrictive Covenants under Federal Law, 73 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 1193 (1973); Charles A.
Sullivan, Revisiting the “Neglected Stepchild”: Antitrust Treatment of Postemployment Re-
straints of Trade, 1977 I
LL
. L.F. 621 (1977); Pamela Carder Fletcher, Antitrust Implications
Arising from the Use of Overly Broad Restrictive Covenants for the Protection of Trade Secrets,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT