Testing the Focal Point Theory of Legal Compliance: The Effect of Third‐Party Expression in an Experimental Hawk/Dove Game

Published date01 March 2005
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1740-1461.2005.00032.x
Date01 March 2005
AuthorJanice Nadler,Richard H. McAdams
Testing the Focal Point Theory
of Legal Compliance: The Effect
of Third-Party Expression in an
Experimental Hawk/Dove Game
Richard H. McAdams and Janice Nadler*
Economic theories of legal compliance emphasize legal sanctions, whereas
psychological and sociological theories stress the perceived legitimacy of
law. Without disputing the importance of either mechanism, we test a third
way that law affects behavior, an expressive theory that claims law influences
behavior by creating a focal point around which individuals coordinate. We
investigated how various forms of third-party “cheap talk” influence the
behavior of subjects in a Hawk/Dove or Chicken game. Despite the players’
conflicting interests, we found that messages highlighting an equilibrium
tend to produce that outcome. Most striking, this result emerged even when
the message was selected by an overtly random, mechanical process. We
obtained a similar result when the message was delivered by a third-party
subject; the latter effect was significantly stronger than the former only
when the subject speaker was selected by a merit-based process. These
results suggest that, in certain circumstances, law generates compliance not
only by sanctions and legitimacy, but also by facilitating coordination
around a focal outcome.
87
*Address correspondence to Richard H. McAdams, University of Illinois College of Law, 504 E.
Pennsylvania Ave., Champaign, IL 61820; phone: 217-333-4385; email: rmcadams@law.uiuc.edu;
Janice Nadler, American Bar Foundation & Northwestern University School of Law, 357 E.
Chicago Ave., Chicago, IL 60611; phone: 312-503-3228; email: jnadler@northwestern.edu.
For their comments on an earlier draft, the authors thank Rachel Croson, Dhammika
Dharmapala, Shari Diamond, Tom Ginsburg, Tom Miles, Jeff Rachlinski, Larry Ribstein, Tom
Ulen, members of the research committees of the American Bar Foundation, and the partici-
pants at law faculty workshops at Connecticut, Florida State, Northwestern, and Virginia and at
the law and economics workshop at Michigan. We also thank Emily Solberg for research assis-
tance. We thank the American Bar Foundation, the Dispute Resolution Research Center of
Northwestern University, Northwestern University School of Law, and the National Science
Foundation for research support. This research was supported by National Science Foundation
Grant SES-0351530.
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 2, Issue 1, 87–123, March 2005
I. Introduction
Law-and-economics theorists commonly view law as a tool for facilitating
cooperation. Legal sanctions change incentives so that individuals will not
defect from Pareto-optimal arrangements. Another important but neglected
effect of law is to facilitate coordination. Because of the publicity commonly
given to and expected for law, legal pronouncements can create common
knowledge about governmental expectations. Even aside from the sanctions
government uses to enforce its expectations, in a coordination situation, a
legal pronouncement can make the prescribed outcome salient or “focal,”
thereby creating self-fulfilling expectations that this outcome will occur.
Broadcasting the rule “drive on the right,” for example, is likely to prompt
some compliance independent of the threat of legal sanctions, merely
because the common knowledge that everyone heard this particular message
makes the named behavior focal.
It is exceedingly easy to overlook this coordinating power of law. One
reason is that two other explanations have long dominated theory and
empiricism on the subject of legal compliance. Most economic analysis
assumes that sanctions are the sole mechanism by which law achieves com-
pliance (via deterrence or incapacitation), while most psychological and
sociological theories emphasize the perceived legitimacy of law as the primary
explanation for compliance (via social and institutional reinforcement of
moral norms). The debate between these camps obscures the possibility of
any alternative. In addition, the common joinder of law with sanctions and
legitimacy makes it extraordinarily difficult to discern whether law has a
power independent of these forces. Finally, even if one is prepared to look
beyond the two prevailing theories, the problem of coordinating among
multiple equilibria stands a bit outside the mainstream of game theory that
is applied to law. Indeed, many law-and-economics scholars think of coordi-
nation as relevant to only a narrow domain of social life that does not include
the conflict that law seeks to resolve.
Despite this resistance, a few theorists have offered coordination as
another mechanism for generating legal compliance, a third reason why
people obey law (Cooter 1998; Garrett & Weingast 1993; Hardin 1989; Hay
& Shleifer 1998:400–01; McAdams 2000a; Posner 2000:177–79). These coor-
dination explanations employ rational choice tools and, like other economic
theories, avoid complex notions of legitimacy. Despite these differences from
psychological and sociological approaches, however, coordination theories
88 Testing the Focal Point Theor y of Legal Compliance
similarly conclude that law can generate some compliance expressively, apart
from its sanctions. Without denying the power of sanctions or legitimacy, the
coordination explanation claims that law influences behavior independently
of either. (There are also rational choice explanations of the expressive
power of law that do not rely on coordination. See, e.g., Dharmapala &
McAdams 2003; McAdams 2000b; Kahan 2000.)
There has, however, been little empirical testing of these novel theo-
ries. Though several experiments document the power of recommendations
in “conflict-free” coordination games (where subjects agree on what
equilibrium is best), law commonly addresses coordination situations with
genuine conflict (where subjects rank the equilibria differently). There has
been almost no testing of the claim that mere “cheap talk” from third parties
can influence behavior in such games. To remedy this gap, we conducted an
experiment to examine whether and how cheap-talk messages influence play
in a Hawk/Dove game. Here, we present our findings, which support the
claim that third-party expression can by itself influence behavior in coordi-
nation situations that model legal disputes. We emphasize two points about
the relationship of the current study to the larger topic of legal compliance.
First, by testing an expressive theory, we do not imply a rejection of com-
pliance theories that emphasize sanctions or legitimacy. Second, by testing
a coordination theory, we do not imply a rejection of other expressive the-
ories. Indeed, we identify below the limited domain in which coordination
theories apply.
This article proceeds as follows. Section II sets forth the coordination
or focal point explanation of law’s expressive power. Section III reviews the
relevant empirical literature on the subject. Section IV describes our exper-
iment. Section V concludes.
II. Coordination Theories of Expressive Law
There is a recent turn in applied game theory toward the importance of
coordination. This new work focuses not on the simple but rare pure coor-
dination game (such as the choice of driving on the left or right side of
the road), but on “mixed-motive” games (Schelling 1960) that combine an
element of conflict with a common interest in coordination. We provide
examples below. For a theory of legal expression, the key is that these games
have multiple equilibria—two or more outcomes that satisfy the Nash crite-
McAdams and Nadler 89

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT