Temporary and permanent migrant selection: Theory and evidence of ability‐search cost dynamics

AuthorJoyce J. Chen,Katrina Kosec,Valerie Mueller
Date01 November 2019
Published date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12617
Rev Dev Econ. 2019;23:1477–1519. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode
|
1477
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12617
REGULAR ARTICLE
Temporary and permanent migrant selection:
theory and evidence of ability‐search cost dynamics*
Joyce J.Chen1
|
KatrinaKosec2
|
ValerieMueller3
*We thank Innovative Development Strategies, Limited, Hak Lim Lee, Mekamu Kedir, Arshad Khurshid, Hina Nazli, and
Sohail Malik for their assistance in the data collection and analysis, and Audrey Light, Robert E. B. Lucas, Pia Orrenius, and
Caroline Theoharides for comments on previous versions of the paper.
1University, Department of
Agricultural,Environmental, and
Development Economics, The Ohio State
University, Columbus, Ohio
2Development Strategy and Governance
Division,International Food Policy
Research Institute, Washington, DC
3Arizona State University School of
Politics and Global Studies, Tempe,
Arizona
Correspondence
Valerie Mueller, Arizona State University
School of Politics and Global Studies,
Tempe, AZ
Email: vmuelle1@asu.edu
Abstract
We integrate two workhorses of the labor literature, the
Roy and search models, to illustrate the implications of mi-
gration duration—specifically, whether it is temporary or
permanent—for patterns of selection. Consistent with our
stylized model, we show that temporary migrants are inter-
mediately selected on education, with weaker selection on
cognitive ability. In contrast, permanent migration is asso-
ciated with strong positive selection on both education and
ability, as it involves finer employee–employer matching
and offers greater returns to experience. Networks are also
more valuable for permanent migration, where search costs
are higher. Labor market frictions explain observed net-
work–skill interactions.
KEYWORDS
migration, networks, Pakistan, self‐selection
JEL CLASSIFICATION
J61; O15
1478
|
CHEN etal.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
As the geographic mobility of workers continues to rise, migration—the movement of individuals and
families—will be as central to economic development as trade. Remittances now far exceed official
aid flows (Ratha etal., 2014), and the skill composition of migrants has increasingly important con-
sequences for destination markets (Card, 1990, 2005; Borjas, 2005, 2006; Ottaviano and Peri, 2012).
But, unlike trade, individuals must move with their “goods,” raising complex questions about both the
motives and the scope for migration. To better understand the impact of migration on both spatial and
economic inequality, we must consider more deeply the migration decision itself (Henderson, 2010;
Young, 2014; Gollin etal., 2017).
The literature has extensively explored the profile of immigrants to inform policy‐makers of po-
tential shifts in labor force composition (Chiquiar and Hanson, 2005; Orrenius and Zavodny, 2005;
McKenzie and Rapoport, 2010; Moraga, 2011, 2013; Bertoli etal., 2013; Kaestner and Malamud,
2014). Previous studies have focused heavily on immigration to the USA, but internal migration
is an increasingly common form of migration worldwide.1
Historically, internal migration has
also been central to economic growth by reallocating rural labor to support the expansion of the
urban manufacturing sector (Lewis, 1954). Yet the extant literature still largely fails to differentiate
among migrants, despite drastically varied motives and skills (Rogerson, 1990; Newbold, 2001,
2012). The profile of internal migrants is of particular concern to the Pakistani government, given
objectives to shift production away from resource‐based exports to manufacturing‐based exports
(News, 2017).
In this paper we take an initial step toward modeling heterogeneity within internal migration by
focusing on variation in the duration of migration episodes among individuals originating from the
same areas and in the same time period. To formalize differences between permanent and temporary
migration, we embed a classic Roy (1951) model with heterogeneous moving costs, as in previous
work (Chiquiar and Hanson, 2005; McKenzie and Rapoport, 2010; Orrenius and Zavodny, 2005),
into a standard search model (Lippman and McCall, 1976). Variation in the duration of migration
opportunities implies important distinctions not only in the decision process but also in patterns of
self‐selection, resulting in differing effects on both origin and destination labor markets. For example,
temporary migration can dampen business cycles by increasing labor supply when wages are high,
while permanent migration can have the opposite effect if labor supply is slow to respond to changes
in market conditions.2
We use data from a unique panel survey of rural households in Pakistan spanning 22 years (1991–
2013) to study the drivers of selection into temporary and permanent internal migration. The data
offer an array of detailed information on worker attributes including education, cognitive ability
(digit span and Raven's test scores), and visible physical ability (height). Our empirical findings
confirm stronger positive selection for permanent migrants than for temporary migrants with re-
spect to formal schooling. However, networks play a nuanced role, both drawing high‐ability types
and dissuading the highly educated. This suggests that, while networks can reduce search costs,
particularly for high‐ability workers, there are limits to what they can do. Using an alternative data
source (Pakistan Bureau of Statistics, 1991, 2002, 2013), we show that our findings on education are
consistent with networks alerting highly educated workers of a low elasticity of demand for skilled
labor at destinations.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents our theoretical framework,
describing the choice between migrating permanently, temporarily, or remaining at the origin. Section
3 describes our dataset, while Section 4 outlines our empirical approach. Sections 5 and 6 present our
main results and robustness checks. Section 7 concludes.
|
1479
CHEN etal.
2
|
THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
In this section we lay out a stylized search model, as in Lippman and McCall (1976), to illustrate key
differences between permanent and temporary migration. We then embed features of a classic Roy
(1951) model to consider how patterns of self‐selection may differ with the type of migration.3
2.1
|
Search with permanent and temporary opportunities
Consider two different types of migration which can be, and often are, employed by different individ-
uals in the same period or by the same individual in different periods.4
The first involves a permanent
employment opportunity and, with it, a permanent change of residence. This type of migration often
occurs over longer distances and requires greater upfront investment (Kleemans, 2015). The second
involves a temporary employment opportunity, necessitating a temporary change of residence and an
eventual return to the origin. This type of migration often occurs over shorter distances, and is more
frequently used as a short‐term diversification or risk‐coping mechanism, requiring relatively little
upfront investment (Bryan etal., 2014). Migration is no longer a binary choice; in each period, the
individual considers both opportunities and selects the one that maximizes expected life‐time utility.
Given differences between the two types of opportunities, different patterns of selection will emerge
as well.
We formalize this choice process using a standard search model. We assume an individual faces a
fixed working life, at the beginning of which he receives a lifetime wage offer in the tehsil (i.e. sub‐dis-
trict) of origin.5
This operates much like unemployment insurance in labor search models, though the
“benefits” in this case do not expire, and ensures that not everyone will choose to engage in permanent
migration during their working life. Each individual also has employment opportunities outside of the
home tehsil, some temporary and some permanent. For ease of exposition, we consider an extreme
case where temporary employment episodes last only a single period, while permanent employment
offers last for the remainder of the working life. However, the implications of the model do not hinge
on the exact duration of temporary and permanent migration episodes. The key distinction is simply
that permanent migration provides employment over a substantially longer period of time than does
temporary migration.
A temporary employment opportunity is available in each period but for only a single period, akin
to entering a spot market for labor at the destination. In this case, the individual observes a wage distri-
bution for temporary employment opportunities that may vary from period to period.6
The individual
must then incur a search cost (i.e. move to the destination) in order to accept the temporary migration
opportunity and obtain a specific wage draw. A permanent offer from outside the home tehsil can also
be obtained in each period. Permanent employment provides a lifetime wage drawn from a known
distribution. In this case, search costs must be incurred before the wage draw is received, consistent
with the notion that permanent migrants often identify a (set of) specific employment opportunities
before migrating.7
We assume that the individual maximizes expected discounted lifetime income, net of search costs,
given the following choices in each period:8
(1) work at home and do not search for another job; (2)
work at home and search; (3) accept a temporary wage offer and do not search; (4) accept a temporary
wage offer and search; or (5) accept a permanent wage offer. The individual may also recall (i.e. return
to) any previous lifetime employment opportunity. Intuitively, a temporary offer will be accepted if
the wage gains exceed the search cost (see the Appendix for details). A permanent wage offer will be
accepted when the wage gains exceeds the continuation value.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT