Teaching Consumer Price Discrimination: An Interdisciplinary Case Study for Business Law Students

Published date01 June 2014
AuthorMatthew A. Edwards
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jlse.12017
Date01 June 2014
Journal of Legal Studies Education
Volume 31, Issue 2, 291–324, Summer 2014
Teaching Consumer Price
Discrimination: An Interdisciplinary
Case Study for Business Law Students
Matthew A. Edwards
I. Introduction
Few business decisions are as important and challenging as a firm’s choice
of how to price its goods and services.1Aside from the obvious need to
cover costs and provide for an acceptable profit, a firm must take care not to
alienate its customers through pricing practices that create the perception
of unfairness or inequity.2Price discrimination—charging different prices
to different consumers for the same good or service3—is one such practice
Associate Professor of Law, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College (CUNY). Aspects of this
article were developed during a summer faculty workshop on case studies at Baruch College. I
want to express gratitude to my colleagues who participated in that seminar, as well as to Sandra
Mullings, Debbie Kaminer and Jay Weiser, all of whom provided helpful feedback on an earlier
version of this article.
1See Robert L. Phillips, Pricing and Revenue Optimization 1 (2005) (noting that “pricing
decisions are commonplace, they can be complex and that they are unusually critical determi-
nants of profitability”).
2Id. at 301 (explaining that when pricing practices are perceived as unfair “there is a chance
that buyers may decline to purchase from a seller either now or in the future for reasons that
might be totally unrelated the absolute price”); Jodie L. Ferguson et al., Procedural and Distributive
Fairness: Determinants of Overall Price Fairness,J. Bus. Ethics (forthcoming 2014) (manuscript at
2), originally published online April 11, 2013 (“[C]onsumers judge whether an offered price is
fair, but they also may judge the fairness of the price-setting practice, procedural fairness, separately
from the fairness of the offered price, outcome fairness.”) (emphasis in original).
3The economic definition of “price discrimination” is provided infra notes 27–31, and accom-
panying text. Other closely related terms in the literature include differential pricing, dynamic
pricing, and revenue management. See Adrian Palmer & Una McMahon-Beattie, Variable Pricing
Through Revenue Management: A Critical Evaluation of Affective Outcomes,31Mgmt. Res. News 189,
190 (2008) (noting that “[r]evenue management has been widely adopted in the airline, hotel
and car rental sectors, among others”).
C2014 The Author
Journal of Legal Studies Education C2014 Academy of Legal Studies in Business
291
292 Vol. 31 / The Journal of Legal Studies Education
that threatens to undermine consumers’ trust in the seller.4The risks of
consumer price discrimination, however, present a bit of a puzzle. After all, if
we put aside the negative connotations of the word “discrimination,”5price
discrimination is a pervasive feature of the business landscape. Myriad firms
charge consumers different prices for the same or nearly the same goods and
services. No one is surprised when they learn that someone else got a better
deal on the same new car or shocked when they see senior citizen discounts
at the movie theater. Only a sociopath would demand that the elderly be
compelled to pay the same amount to see Transformers IV in 3D.
Nevertheless, it is generally agreed that price discrimination can, in
some circumstances at least, be an extraordinarily unpopular business prac-
tice.6The perils of price discrimination are well illustrated by the Ama-
zon.com case. Although the incident is almost fifteen years old, it has become
the standard reference in law review7and business literature8on the risks
of consumer price discrimination. The facts of the controversy are rather
simple. In late 2000, customers discovered that Amazon.com was varying its
prices online for the exact same products.9Rumors swirled that the price
customization was based on demographic data that the e-commerce giant
4See Una McMahon Beattie et al., Does the Customer Trust You?, in Revenue Management: A Prac-
tical Pricing Perspective 55, 55 (Ian Yeoman & Una McMahon-Beattie, eds., 2011) (noting
that “price discrimination which is implicit in Revenue Management systems may undermine
trust in an organization, when buyers perceive that they have been treated less fairly than other
buyers”); Ellen Garbarino & Sarah Maxwell, Consumer Response to Norm-Breaking Pricing Events
in E-Commerce,63J. Bus. Res. 1066 (2010) (treating price discrimination as a norm-breaking
business practice).
5Babette E.L. Boliek, FCC Regulation Versus Antitrust: How Net Neutrality Is Defining the Boundaries,
52 B.C. L. Rev. 1627, 1678 (2011) (noting that the term “‘discrimination’ has a negative popular
association”) (footnotes omitted). In his book on pricing, Robert Phillips chooses to use the
term “price differentiation” to avoid the negative connotations of “discrimination.” Phillips,
supra note 1, at 74.
6See infra notes 92–97.
7See Amy Kapczynski, The Cost of Price: Why and How to Get Beyond Intellectual Property Internalism,59
UCLA L. Rev. 970, 1016 (2012); Douglas M. Kochelek, Data Mining and Antitrust,22Harv. J.L.
&Tech.515, 515 (2009); Lior Jacob Strahilevitz, Reputation Nation: Law in an Era of Ubiquitous
Personal Information,102Nw.U.L.Rev. 1667, 1732–33 (2008); Jonathan Zittrain, Privacy 2.0,
2008 U. Chi. Legal F. 65, 71.
8See Garbarino & Maxwell, supra note 4, at 1066–67; Kalyan T. Talluri & Garrett J. van
Ryzin, The Theory and Practice of Revenue Management 614–16 (2005).
9Some consumers were offered discounts between 20 percent and 40 percent on select DVDs.
Talluri & Van Ryzin, supra note 8, at 615.
2014 / Teaching Consumer Price Discrimination 293
had collected on its customers. Faced with a “huge public outcry,”10 Ama-
zon.com retreated from its differential pricing practices,11 claiming that the
price variations were due merely to a “random price test.”12 The company
gave refunds to consumers whose prices were affected by the firm’s differen-
tial pricing13 and issued a somewhat apologetic press release that referred to
the price test as a mistake.14
10Ronald Leenes, Do They Know Me? Deconstructing Identifiability,4U. Ottawa L. & Tech. J. 135,
146 n. 36 (2007). A “huge public outcry” may be a bit of an overstatement, but it certainly
created significant buzz in the relatively new world of e-commerce. See Kochelek, supra note
7, at 515 (stating that the incident precipitated a “public outcry”); Robert M. Weiss & Ajay K.
Mehrotra, Online Dynamic Pricing: Efficiency, Equity and the Future of E-Commerce, 6Va.J.L.&Tech.
11, ¶ 1 (2001), available at http://www.vjolt.net/vol6/issue2/v6i2-a11-Weiss.html (claiming that
the Amazon.com customers were “startled and quite upset when they learned that the online
mega-store was charging different customers different prices for the same DVD movies”).
11Mark MacCarthy, New Directions in Privacy: Disclosure, Unfairness and Externalities,6I/S: J. L.
& Pol’y for Info. Soc’y 425, 465 (2011) (“Consumer reaction to Amazon’s attempt to use
information about repeat customers to charge them a higher price, thereby punishing loyalty,
was so uniformly negative that the practice was abandoned.”); See also Christopher Paul Boam,
The Internet, Information and the Culture of Regulatory Change: A Modern Renaissance,9Commlaw
Conspectus 175, 80 (2001) (noting that Amazon.com “backtracked after unintended exposure
and consumer furor”).
12See News Release, Amazon.com, Amazon.com Issues Statement Regarding Random Price Test-
ing (Sept. 27, 2000), available at http://phx.corporate-ir.net/phoenix.zhtml?c=176060&p=irol-
newsArticle_Print&ID=502821&highlight=.
13Id.
14The full news release reads as follows:
Some news reports over the last several weeks have incorrectly characterized a recent
Amazon.com random price test as a test based on customer demographic information.
These reports were incorrect and were not based on the facts.
Contrary to these reports, Amazon.com varied the discount levels on a totally random
basis, not with respect to customer demographic information. The purpose of the test
was to determine how much sales are affected by lower prices. In retrospect, this random
testing was a mistake, and we regret it because it created uncertainty and complexity for our
customers, and our job is to simplify shopping for customers. That is why, more than two
weeks ago, in response to customer feedback, we changed our policy to protect customers
should we ever do random price testing again (and currently we have no plans to do so).
Now, if we ever do such a test again, we’ll automatically give customers who purchased a
test item the lowest test price for that item at the conclusion of the test period—thereby
ensuring that all customers pay the lowest available price. Under this new policy, by Sept. 14,
we had refunded to 6,896 customers an average of $3.10 as a result of the DVD random price
test. “We’ve never tested and we never will test prices based on customer demographics,”

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT