Tax Sharing in Insurance Markets: A Useful Parameterization

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1539-6975.2013.01528.x
AuthorChristelle Viauroux
Date01 December 2014
Published date01 December 2014
©
DOI: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2013.01528.x
907
Tax Sharing in Insurance Markets:
A Useful Parameterization
Christelle Viauroux
Abstract
We use a principal–agent framework to evaluate the economic impacts of
imposing a tax on insurance payment in presence of moral hazard using
a Gamma conditional distribution of losses. Our results show that any tax
paid by the insured would lower his effort to prevent loss, hence increasing
insurance payments and decreasing profits. This result is reinforced as the
insured becomes more risk averse unless the distribution of losses is uni-
form. We find that any decrease in the insurer’s tax share would generate
an overall decrease in welfare unless the insured characteristics prevent him
from reacting to the policy.
Introduction
During the past few years, much attention has been placed on possible revenue
sources to pay for health care. The recent political interest has been to tax insurance
companies: the Baucus plan levies a nondeductible excise tax of 40 percent on
insurance companies. In many insurance markets, the insurance provider determines
the premium based on a coverage amount chosen by the insured. As a result, a tax on
the premium amount corresponds to a proportional tax on the coverage amount. For
example, in the long-term care insurance market, the future insured is prompted to
choose a monthly benefit during the contract negotiation. In this article, we analyze
the economic impacts of imposing a tax on payments out to the insured. The question
then is: should the insurance provider pay the full amount of the tax as is proposed
or should the insured bear a portion of it? And in case the insured bears a portion
of it, should this portion be attributed uniformly across contract types? To answer
these questions, we generalize the analysis to a case where the tax could be shared
between the insurer and the insured.
Unfortunately,the presence of asymmetric information in insurance markets compli-
cates the analysis (Chiappori and Salanie, 1997, 2000; Dionne, Doherty,and Fombaron,
2000,Forthcoming;Villeneuve, 2000; Abbring, Chiappori,andPinquet, 2003, to name a
Christelle Viaurouxis in the Department of Economics at the University of Maryland, Baltimore
County. She can be contacted at ckviauro@umbc.edu. The author is thankful to G. Dionne,
Editor,and an anonymous referee for their very useful comments. She is also grateful to Vilmos
Komornik, Richard Pollard, and WendyTakacs for very helpful discussions and feedback.
1
The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2013, Vol. 81, No. 4, 907–941
908 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE
few). The lack of care enforcementon the part of the insurer, that is, moral hazard, com-
plicates the welfare outcome of any policy aiming at redistributing health care cove-
rage (see, e.g., Dionne et al., 1997; Doherty and Smetters, 2005, for empirical evidence
of moral hazard in insurance markets; see Ketsche, 2004, for an empirical analysis of
the impact of a subsidy on welfare). Indeed, the more health insurance an individual
acquires, the lower his risk. This improves the social welfare of those with greater
coverage. But as his coverage increases, the insured subsequently invests less in self-
protection and consequently increases his use of health care services. This increased
demand causes increases use of services, which results in higher prices, thus having
the opposing effect on social welfare. Because risk-averse consumers would not pur-
chase this additional care if they had to pay the full cost, the value of the extra service to
consumers falls short of the social cost of producing that care. Therefore,although risk
sharing increases social well-being, the change in moral hazard induces welfare loss.
Early theoretical studies on moral hazard in insurance markets (Arrow, 1963; Pauly,
1968; Shavell, 1979) proposed solutions to the moral hazard issue. The solutions inclu-
ded (1) an incomplete coverage against loss, which gives the individual an incentive
to prevent loss by exposing him to some financial risk (see Wang,Chung, and Tzeng,
2008; Chiappori et al., 1997; Koc, 2011, for empirical evidence of this solution in the
market for automobile insurance and for physician services insurance, respectively)
and (2) the observation of care, to link it to the premium or coverage in the event of a
claim. The impossibility to fully observe care, however, has led to an increasing lite-
rature on the design of optimal contracts (Lewis and Sappington, 1995; Winter, 1992,
2000; Gollier, 2000; Doherty and Smetters, 2005).
In this article, we use a framework allowing for a distribution of losses with care
reducing both the probability of a loss and the size of a loss (MasColell, Whinsten, and
Green, 1995).1In our model, an agent insures with a principal. Both have property
rights to an uncertain income stream that represents a possible loss from current
wealth. The random income stream depends on care or effort on the part of the agent,
to be taken in the future. The principal establishes a sharing rule on how to share
the random income stream. The principal–agent relationship involves moral hazard,
because the agent’s effort to avoid any loss is unobservable by the principal, whereas
it ultimately affects the expected profit. Therefore, the principal wants to use the
contract to induce the agent to exert optimal effort to invest in self-protection and/or
loss reduction.
1Economic models of moral hazard in insurance markets differ on their assumptions about the
impact of greater care on the distribution of losses faced by the insured (Winter, 2000). When
the loss is assumed to be random, the literature distinguishes the effects of moral hazard on
two types of expenditures on the part of the insured (Ehrlich and Becker,1972). The first type
of expenditures, called self-protection, reduces the probability of an accident. It refers to an
increase in the probability of a zero loss, with no change in the conditional distribution. The
second type, called loss reduction, refers to a first-order stochastic reductionwith no change in
the probability of a loss. In these two cases, the optimal insurance contract is characterized by a
premium and a coverage amount that may depend on the loss amount. Weuse a third approach
allowing for an arbitrary distribution of losses with care reducing both the probability of a loss
and the size of a loss.
TAX SHARING IN INSURANCE MARKETS 909
It is well known, however, that the principal–agent problem (Laffont and Martimort,
2002) is difficult to solve when effort is a continuous variable. Its tractability depends
on the ability to simplify an infinite number of global incentive constraints corres-
ponding to an infinite number of possible effort levels and replace them by a local
incentive constraint to induce the maximum effort from the agent. This last condi-
tion states that the agent is indifferent between choosing a given level of effort and
increasing it by a slight amount when he receives the risk premium. This so-called
“first-order approach” has been one of the most debated issues in contract theory.
Mirrlees (1975) shows that the problem may sometimes have no optimal solution
in the class of unbounded sharing rules. Rogerson (1985) shows that the “original”
first-order approach (with an infinite number of global incentive constraints) gives
the same solutions as the first-order approach when the following two properties are
satisfied. The first, the maximum likelihood ratio property (MLRP), ensures that the
agent is rewarded in the state of nature that is most informative in that he has exer-
ted positive effort. The second property is the convexity of the distribution function
condition (CDFC), which ensures that higher profit (of the principal) is a signal of
higher effort on the part of the agent. The problem is that the CDFC property is very
restrictive and tremendously limits the list of possible distributions that can be used.
Simple distributions, such as the exponential distribution function, do not verify the
latter property. Jewitt (1988), however, shows that the CDFC can be relaxed, provided
that the agent’s utility function satisfies certain properties.
We show that the Gamma conditional distribution of loss verifies the first-order vali-
dation conditions of Jewitt (1988). We characterize the optimal insurance contract in
presence of taxation using this distribution as well as a representation of the agent’s
preferences also satisfying Jewitt’s conditions. We then analyze how the tax affects
equilibrium outcomes. More specifically, we analyze how increasing the agent’s share
of the tax impacts his investment in self-protection/loss reduction, the principal’s ave-
rage payouts, the principal’s profit, and the overall social welfare. We simulate the
above effects for different measures of risk aversion of the agent and for different
characteristics of his preferences and his likelihood to contract with alternative pro-
viders. We present the characteristics of the optimal contract and the impact of an
increase in the insured tax share in case of a simple utility function. The closed-form
solutions to the problem emphasize the good properties of the Gamma distribution.
Still, we check the robustness of our results by using alternative loss distributions:
one proposed by Rogerson (1985) and one proposed by LiCalzi and Spaeter (2003).
To the best of our knowledge, this is the most general, yet most detailed, analysis of
the impact on welfare of imposing a tax on insurance output.
Our results show that maximum effort of the insured is achieved when the insurer
pays the full amount of the tax. An exception to the result occurs when losses happen
to be uniformly distributed. In this case, the insured may increase his effort because he
is unable to anticipate the size of his future losses and of his insurance tax amount. If
the tax share paid by the insuredwere to increase, we find average insurance payments
out to the insured would be higher, unless the provider recognizes the insured has
made only marginal effort to self-protect and the insured is uncertain about keeping
insurance with them. This suggests that the insurance provider would compensate

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT