Tax havens, income shifting, and redistributive taxation

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12335
AuthorYu‐Bong Lai
Published date01 February 2019
Date01 February 2019
Received: 23 November 2017
|
Accepted: 27 August 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12335
Tax havens, income shifting, and redistributive
taxation
YuBong Lai
Department of Public Finance, National
Chengchi University, Taipei, Taiwan, ROC
Correspondence
YuBong Lai, Department of Public Finance,
National Chengchi University, No. 64, Sec. 2,
ZhiNan Road, Taipei 11605, Taiwan, ROC.
Email: yblai@nccu.edu.tw
Funding information
Ministry of Science and Technology (Taiwan,
ROC), Grant/Award Number: 1072410H
004 013
Abstract
This paper investigates the effects of tax havens on
nonhaven countriesredistributive policies. We consider
that a nonhaven country contains individuals with different
labor productivities. A tax is imposed on the income, and the
revenues are evenly distributed. The tax rate is determined
by majority voting, which reflects the median voters
preferences. The presence of havens gives rise to the
mobility of tax bases, which may increase the nonhaven
countrys tax rate in two ways. First, it leads to a median
voter with a lower productivity; second, it may enlarge the
marginal tax revenue from raising the tax rate. In addition,
we find that a stricter antihavens regulation may lower the
tax rate. We further show that income shifting is likely to
reduce the amount of the transfers. The case of tax evasion
is also taken into consideration.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The issue of tax havens has been the focus of much attention and debate. A number of studies have discussed the
impacts of havens on the tax policies of nonhaven countries, and most of them have been directed at efficiency
topics. The redistributive problems, however, have been overlooked. According to Zucman (2014), about 8% of
global household net financial wealth is held in tax havens, which amounted to about $7.6 trillion at the end of
2013. In a more recent study, Alstadsæter, Johannesen, and Zucman (2017a) found that the amount of global
offshore wealth is equivalent to about 10% of world gross domestic product (GDP). Zucman (2014, p. 140) claims
that the worlds offshore wealth is large enough to significantly affect measure of the inequality of
wealth.Moreover, the higher mobility of tax bases has significantly restricted the scope for redistribution
through taxation. People are concerned that the presence of tax havens will erode the foundation of the
redistribution policy, or the welfare state (AviYonah, 2000; Steinmo, 1994). It is thus necessary to investigate the
effects of tax havens on nonhaven countriesredistributive policies.
J Public Econ Theory. 2019;21:8197. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
81
ARTICLE
This paper focuses on general redistributive programs, which affect almost all members of a society. Such
programs are likely to reflect the preferences of the majority (Persson & Tabellini, 2000). To characterize this
feature, we allow the redistributive program to be determined through a political process. Two political
candidates compete f or office, and they commi t to their announced pro gram once they are in offi ce. The
equilibrium tax rate reflects the preferences of the median voter.
1
This setting is differ ent from that in the
existing literature, in which governments seek to maximize social welfare or to maximize tax revenues.
Redistributive con cerns usually do not play an impor tant role in the related literatur e, whereas they are essential
in determining the ta x rate in this paper.
Moreover, the literature regarding tax havens focuses on capital income or profit income. However, according
to Atkinson, Piketty, and Saez (2011), over the past 30 years top income shares have increased substantially. They
argue that this result is due in part to an unprecedented increase in top wage incomes. Thus, wage income
constitutes a larger fraction of top incomes than in the past. Smith, Yagan, Zidar, and Zwick (2017) also confirm this
view. They find that most top earners are working rich, not passive owners of accumulated capital. They also show
that 61% of top Scorporation income is wage income in disguise. To characterize these features, we deal with labor
income and personal taxation.
We aim to address how shifting income to havens affects the nonhaven countrys redistributive policy. To this end,
we consider a small open economy, in which live a large number of people endowed with different labor productivities.
A tax is imposed on the income, and all of the proceeds are evenly distributed among the people. We first consider a
case without havens, in which individualsideal tax rates decrease with their productivities, and the median vo ter is the
individual with the median productivity. Then, we introduce tax havens, through which rich people can dodge the local
taxes. Shifting income to havens requires a fixed cost, which is regarded as a social waste.
The standard taxcompetition model shows that the mobility of tax bases tends to reduce the tax rates in the
hightax countries, because when tax bases are interjurisdictionally mobile, an increase in the tax rate generates
less revenue. This result does not necessarily hold in the presence of havens, which give rise to the mobility of tax
bases. We find that the mobility of tax bases may increase the marginal tax revenues from raising the tax rate,
inducing the median voter to choose a higher tax rate.
Moreover, the presence of havens can raise the tax rate in the nonhaven country in a second way. When income
shifting is possible, the income shifters can avoid domestic taxes, and they will endorse the highest tax rate to
receive the largest amount in terms of a transfer payment. Recall that they prefer lower tax rates when income
shifting is not allowed. The change in their stance on the tax rate results in a different median voter with a lower
productivity, who prefers a higher tax rate.
Since the financial crisis of 20082009, progress has been made in reducing bank secrecy, including the Foreign
Account Tax Compliance Act (FATCA) in the United States, and the new global standard on the Automatic
Exchange of Information (AEOI) of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).
Although such policies are probably unable to eliminate income shifting behavior (Johannesen & Zucman, 2014;
Zucman, 2014), they raise the costs of using the offshore banking service.
2
The impacts of these antihaven
regulations on the tax rate in the nonhaven countries are another concern of this paper.
We find that the effects of a higher cost of shifting income, denoted by
c
, on the tax rate are ambiguous. On the
one hand, a higher
c
gives rise to a median voter with a larger productivity, and thus he endorses a lower tax rate.
On the other hand, the marginal tax revenues from raising the tax rate either increase or decrease with
c
. When the
labor productivities follow a Pareto distribution, a reverse relationship between
c
and the tax rate is more likely to
occur when the initial tax rate is higher, or the distribution of productivities is more unequal.
1
Here, we assume that voterspolicy preferences are shaped by their economic situation. Such selfinterested policy preferences have been empirically
confirmed by, for example, Alesina and La Ferrara (2005), Kau and Rubin (1979), Lupu and Pontusson (2011), and Margalit (2013).
2
According to Zucman (2014), those regulations would make it more difficult for fairly wealthy individuals to avoid or evade taxes through offshore banks.
However, ultrarich individuals are still able to use the more sophisticated services provided by offshore banks to dodge taxes.
82
|
LAI

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT